Large-Scale Integration of Deferrable Demand and Renewable Energy Sources

1 Large-Scale Integration of Deferrable Demand and Renewable Energy Sources Anthony Papavasiliou, Student Member, IEEE, and Shmuel S. Oren, Fellow, I...
19 downloads 0 Views 6MB Size
1

Large-Scale Integration of Deferrable Demand and Renewable Energy Sources Anthony Papavasiliou, Student Member, IEEE, and Shmuel S. Oren, Fellow, IEEE,,

Abstract—We present a stochastic unit commitment model for assessing the impacts of the large-scale integration of renewable energy sources and deferrable demand in power systems in terms of reserve requirements. We analyze three demand response paradigms for assessing the benefits of demand flexibility: the centralized co-optimization of generation and demand by the system operator, demand bids and the coupling of renewable resources with deferrable loads. We motivate coupling as an alternative for overcoming the drawbacks of the two alternative demand response options and we present a dynamic programming algorithm for coordinating deferrable demand with renewable supply. We present simulation results for a model of the Western Electricity Coordinating Council. Index Terms—Wind power generation, load management, power generation scheduling.

I. I NTRODUCTION The key disadvantage of renewable resources relative to conventional dispatchable generation is their high variability, their unpredictable fluctuation and the fact that their output can only be controlled to a limited extent. Demand response can strongly benefit the large-scale integration of these resources. In order to accurately assess the impacts of renewable energy integration and demand response integration on power system operations it is necessary to represent the balancing operations of the remaining grid by using a unit commitment model. The purpose of this paper is to incorporate a fairly detailed representation of deferrable demand resources in a unit commitment and economic dispatch model, in order to assess the benefits of demand response in reducing reserve requirements and operating costs in scenarios of large-scale renewable energy integration. As we discuss in the literature review below, existing work in this area either does not model the deferrable nature of various demand response resources (e.g. electric vehicle charging, agricultural pumping or certain residential appliances), or does not account for the uncertainty that is introduced by the large-scale integration of renewable resources. Both of these features need to be accounted for simultaneously in a unit commitment and economic dispatch model in order to accurately assess the impact of demand response integration on reserve requirements and operating costs in cases of large-scale renewable energy integration. One additional contribution of this paper is to explore the direct coupling of deferrable consumers with renewable resources into a virtual resource through a contractual agreement based on a strike price that limits the impact of the coupled A. Papavasiliou and S. S. Oren are with the Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research, UC Berkeley, Berkeley, CA, 94720 USA (e-mail: [email protected]; [email protected]).

system on the rest of the network. The coupling contract that we present attempts to overcome various institutional or technological barriers associated with alternative demand response paradigms. A. Literature Review A major economic barrier in the large-scale integration of renewable resources is the high investment cost of backup reserves that can guarantee the reliable operation of the system. Stochastic unit commitment models can be used for quantifying reserve requirements as well as the impacts of renewable integration on operating costs. For this reason, numerous renewable integration studies based on unit commitment have been performed recently by Ruiz et al. [1], Sioshansi and Short [2], Wang et al. [3], Contantinescu et al. [4], Tuohy et al. [5], Morales et al. [6], Bouffard et al., Papavasiliou et al. [7] and Papavasiliou and Oren [8]. However, these publications focus exclusively on the impact of renewable supply uncertainty on power system operations and do not account for the potential benefits of demand response integration. The power system economics literature often represents demand response through demand functions. Sioshansi and Short [2] use this approach in the context of a unit commitment model and Borenstein and Holland [9] and Joskow and Tirole [10], [11] also use this approach for analyzing retail pricing. However, many flexible consumption tasks are best characterized as deferrable, in the sense that consumers need a certain amount of energy within a certain time window. As such, deferrable demand behaves much like a hydro or storage resource from the view point of the system operator. Electric vehicle charging, agricultural pumping, pre-cooling, and residential consumption such as laundry fit this characterization. In a recent publication, Sioshansi [12] considers a unit commitment model where electric vehicles are centrally cooptimized and dispatched by the system operator along with controllable generation resources. This model extends the state of the art by explicitly representing the deferrable nature of electric vehicle energy demand. However, the model is deterministic and does not account for the uncertainty associated with renewable energy supply. Both demand response paradigms discussed previously are currently limited by institutional barriers. The real-time benefits of demand-side bidding require real-time pricing at the retail level. This possibility was introduced by Schweppe et al. [13] and is discussed by Borenstein et al. [14]. However, there is strong political opposition to this approach as it exposes retail consumers to the volatility of wholesale electricity prices.

2

In addition, real-time prices often fail to convey the economic value of demand response due to the non-convex costs of system operations. This effect has been reported by Sioshansi [2], who notes that the failure of real-time prices to capture non-convexities induces a dispatch of deferrable resources that results in excessive startup and minimum load costs. The central co-optimization of demand-side resources, renewable supply and generator dispatch discussed by Sioshansi [12] represents the most efficient approach for exploiting demandside flexibility. However, this paradigm cannot be implemented in practice as the system operator dispatches the system at a bulk scale and cannot control individual retail loads. In addition, the optimization problem is too complex to solve. An alternative demand response paradigm that is not discussed in this paper has been set forth by Hirst and Kirby [15] and Kirby [16], whereby flexible loads deliver services to the ancillary services market. According to this paradigm, an aggregator bids on behalf of load aggregations for providing ancillary services to the system operator. The aggregator coordinates aggregate consumption by a price-based or direct control method. The technical feasibility of demandside aggregation for the provision of spinning reserve has been studied in practice by Eto [17]. As ancillary services requirements are expected to increase due to renewable energy integration, this solution could prove lucrative for users who would be willing to respond to the instantaneous needs of power system operators. However, there are concerns about defining market products that correspond to the types of services that loads can actually offer, which raises the need for reform in existing electricity markets. A stream of literature with a focus on strategic demand-side bidding in unit commitment models has been developed by Lamont and Rajan [18] and Zhang et al. [19]. Such models typically involve a utility owning both generation assets as well as own demand, where the utility strives to optimize market bids while accounting for uncertainty in competitors’ bids as well as the impact of its own bids on market prices. A literature review is provided by David and Wen [20]. This literature focuses on strategic interactions among bidders and is therefore not explored further in this paper. B. Paper Contributions The methodological contribution of this paper is to present a stochastic unit commitment model that can be used in order to quantify the benefits of deferrable demand in mitigating the increased operating costs and day-ahead reserve requirements resulting from the random fluctuation of renewable energy supply. The use of stochastic planning models for simulating long-term market equilibrium in order to quantify generation investment in the face of long-term uncertainty was recently introduced by Ehrenmann and Smeers [21]. Analogously, the stochastic unit commitment model presented in this paper is used in order to simulate the two-stage operation of dayahead and real-time electricity markets. The use of a stochastic unit commitment model for the purpose of simulating the operations of a day-ahead market introduces computational challenges that can be addressed by using an appropriate

scenario selection technique to discretize the uncertainty space of the problem [22], [23], [24], [5] and exploiting the decomposable structure of the resulting stochastic optimization problem [25], [26], [27], [28], [3], [29]. These computational challenges have been addressed in previous work by the authors [7], [8] and will not be the focus of this paper. The modeling contribution of this paper is to simultaneously incorporate deferrable demand response resources and stochastic renewable supply resources in the stochastic unit commitment and economic dispatch models. The demand bidding models cited earlier [10], [11], [14], [2] do not account for inter-temporal elasticities, thereby making demand appear independent across time periods. In the present paper we highlight the inadequacy of this approach in representing deferrable demand. On the other hand, the work of Sioshansi [12] does not account for the uncertainty introduced by renewable energy supply and inflexible demand fluctuations. In this paper we extend existing models by simultaneously modeling the intertemporal dependency of deferrable demand and renewable supply uncertainty. The third and final contribution of this paper is to present a contractual alternative for coupling the operations of renewable resources with deferrable demand that attempts to overcome the implementation barriers associated with centralized load dispatch and real-time pricing of retail loads, and compare the relative performance of each demand response paradigm in terms of system operating costs. The motivation of directly coupling renewable generation with deferrable demand is to create a net resource or load that appears ‘behind the meter’ from the point of view of the system operator, thus limiting the risk that the system operator needs to offset by procuring reserves. The California ISO provides a representative example of the institutional and regulatory difficulties that render coupling a pragmatic approach to the large-scale integration of demand response. The Board of Governors of the California ISO recently appraised the current status of integrating distributed resources, including demand response, in the California ISO energy market [30]. The presentation and executive summary justify, in detail, why the market-based integration of demand response is far from foreseeable, which justifies the coupling approach that the authors present in this paper for overcoming exactly these institutional difficulties. The most that the California ISO can expect currently from distributed resources are rough estimates that can be incorporated into load forecasts but not direct accounting of demand response in the dispatch or unit commitment of the system [30]. The remaining paper is organized as follows. In Section II we provide an overview of the components of our model. In Section III we describe in detail the demand flexibility models that we consider in our analysis. Results from a test case of the Western Electricity Coordinating Council are presented in Section IV. In Section V we discuss the conclusions of our work. II. M ODEL OVERVIEW In Fig. 1 we present a diagram of a stochastic unit commitment model that accounts both for the fluctuations of

3

Fig. 1.

Overview of the model.

renewable supply as well as the benefits of demand response in absorbing these fluctuations. Uncertainty in the model is driven by renewable supply and demand. Demand resources in the system are categorized as inflexible (firm) consumers with stochastic consumption patterns and deferrable consumers that require a fixed amount of energy within the day and adapt their instantaneous consumption patterns to the prevailing system conditions. The model of Fig. 1 serves two purposes. The decision support module in the upper portion of the figure simulates day-ahead market operations and is used for determining day-ahead reserve requirements when deferrable demand contributes to absorbing the variability of renewable energy supply. The evaluation module in the lower portion of the figure uses the reserves committed by the day-ahead model in order to compare the real-time operating costs of the system under the three demand response paradigms that are discussed in the introduction of the paper. In what follows we describe each component of the model in further detail. A. Statistical Models The stochastic unit commitment model presented in Section II-B which is used for determining the optimal amount of reserves in the system accounts for firm demand and renewable supply uncertainty. We use a second order autoregressive model for modeling demand and load. We assume that firm demand and renewable production are independent in the stochastic unit commitment model. Our analysis in this paper focuses on wind power resources. Due to the nonlinear relation of wind speed to wind power, we develop a stochastic model of wind speed and use an appropriately calibrated static power curve to determine the corresponding wind power production. We employ a data set published by the National Renewable Energy Resources Laboratory (NREL) which provides hourly time series of wind

speed at various geographic locations over a year. In order to calibrate our wind speed model to the available data, we first remove seasonal and diurnal patterns, and subsequently transform the data set in order to obtain a strictly stationary Gaussian data set. The autoregressive parameters of the strictly stationary data set are estimated using the Yule-Walker equations. Our methodology follows Brown et al. [31], Torres et al. [32] and Callaway [33]. The calibration and simulation procedure and the fit of the model to the available data set is presented in Papavasiliou and Oren [34]. The calibration of firm demand follows as a special case, since the strictly stationary data set that is obtained after removing seasonal and diurnal patterns is already approximately Gaussian. The fit of the stochastic demand model to the data is shown in Fig. 2. In the present analysis we use a single-area wind model and ignore transmission constraints in order to focus on the impact of demand response. The effect of transmission constraints in a system with multi-area renewable supply and demand response will be addressed in future work. The problem of balancing the schedules of coupled resources with the rest of the system while respecting transmission constraints would be addressed by the system operator and would be reflected in locational marginal prices from the point of view of aggregators. In the framework of a nodal market any transaction is exposed to congestion charges that the aggregator can hedge by buying financial transmission rights (FTRs) [35]. B. Stochastic Unit Commitment In order to determine the day-ahead reserves that are committed by the system operator in order to accommodate the simultaneous integration of renewable supply and deferrable demand, we formulate a unit commitment model which assumes that the system operator co-optimizes the dispatch

4

Fig. 2.

Probability distribution function of inflexible demand.

of flexible loads and generation resources. The uncertainty stemming from renewable supply and load fluctuations is represented in terms of a discrete set of scenarios S. The stochastic unit commitment model is formulated as a two-stage decision model where the first stage represents day-ahead unit commitment and the second stage represents real-time economic dispatch in the hour-ahead market, in hourly intervals, subsequent to the realization of uncertainty. As we illustrate in Fig. 1, we use this model to determine the day-ahead schedule of slow reserves assuming that the system operator can cooptimize the dispatch of generators and deferrable loads. (SU C) X:X X min πs (Kg ugst + Sg vgst + Cg pgst )

(1)

g∈G s∈S t∈T

s.t. X

pgst = Dst + est , s ∈ S, t ∈ T

(2)

g∈G

X

est = R, s ∈ S

(3)

t∈T

0 ≤ est ≤ C, s ∈ S, t ∈ T

(4)

ugst = wgt , vgst = zgt , g ∈ Gs , s ∈ S, t ∈ T

(5)

(p, e, u, v, w, z) ∈ D.

(6)

The set of generators G in the system is partitioned into a set of slow generators Gs for which commitment decisions are fixed in the day-ahead time frame, and fast generators that can adjust their commitment schedule in the second stage. This approach is inspired by the work of Ruiz et al. [1], and adopted by Papavasiliou et al. [7]. First-stage decisions wgt , zgt represent the binary unit commitment and startup decisions for slow generators. The second-stage decisions include the unit commitment, startup and power output of all generators, denoted respectively as ugst , vgst and pgst . The dispatch of deferrable loads is also a second-stage decision variable denoted as est . The objective function of Eq. (1) minimizes operating costs. Startup costs, minimum load costs and constant fuel costs for each generator g are denoted respectively as Sg , Kg and Cg . The model is solved for a 24-hour horizon with hourly time steps. Power balance is

enforced in Eq. (2). The net demand Dst , which is the net of firm demand minus renewable power supply, represents the source of uncertainty. The constraint of Eq. (3) requires that deferrable loads be supplied an amount of energy R within a given time window and Eq. (4) enforces a limit of C on the consumption (e.g. charge) rate of deferrable loads. The non-anticipativity constraints on first-stage decisions is enforced in Eq. (5). Note that all generators, including slow units, can adjust their production level in the second stage. The set D includes generator capacity constraints, ramping constraints, and minimum up and down times, where bold fonts indicate vectors. The notation of the stochastic unit commitment model and the economic dispatch models that are presented subsequently is summarized in the appendix. The solution of the stochastic unit commitment model is described in detail by Papavasiliou [36]. The scenario selection algorithm used in the stochastic unit commitment model of this paper is inspired by importance sampling, whereby scenarios are selected according to their effect on expected cost and weighed such that their selection does not bias the objective function of the stochastic unit commitment formulation. The decomposition algorithm which is employed relies on a Lagrangian relaxation scheme for scenario decomposition. Both the scenario selection algorithm and decomposition algorithm developed by the authors account for transmission constraints, load uncertainty and renewable supply uncertainty as well as generator and transmission line outages [7], [8]. However, transmission constraints and element outages are not accounted for in this paper in order to isolate the effect of demand response on absorbing the uncertainty of renewable energy supply. The centralized stochastic unit commitment model presented in this section presumes the ability of the system operator to centrally monitor and control individual loads. This is unrealistic in practice due to technological and institutional reasons. Nevertheless, such a centralized model provides a useful benchmark for estimating the maximal potential benefits of demand response, and the efficiency losses of decentralizing demand response through load aggregators. For this reason, such a centralized demand response model has been previously employed in the literature [12]. The aggregate load represented in Eqs. (2) - (4) can be perceived as a collection of a large number of identical deferrable loads that place identical requests for energy demand, are characterized by the same power rating and share power consumption equally across the entire population. In future research the authors intend to exploit high performance computing in order to incorporate a more detailed representation of deferrable loads according to their energy demand, capacity rating, and availability for charge. In order to draw a comparison between the operating cost impact of the three demand response policies discussed in this paper, we use a single stochastic unit commitment model in order to model day-ahead market interactions. As a result, there is a misrepresentation of recourse as far as the alternative demand response models are concerned. In effect, the first stage reserve commitment decisions are somewhat overoptimistic, in assuming that the system operator can centrally

5

coordinate generation and demand response resources. The price of this simplification is that we are obtaining a lower bound on the performance of demand response, a pessimistic assessment of how different demand response strategies will perform. As a result, we are able to isolate the effect of demand response on operating costs and draw a consistent comparison among different demand response paradigms. III. D EMAND F LEXIBILITY In this section we describe each of the three demand response paradigms that were discussed in the introduction and how these are integrated in the economic dispatch model of real-time operations. The optimal unit commitment and startup ? ? schedules wgt , zgt determined by the optimal solution of the stochastic unit commitment model in the day-ahead phase are used as input to an economic dispatch model for each realization of uncertainty ω. As in the case of the stochastic unit commitment model, the horizon T of the problem is 24 hours in hourly time steps. A. Centralized Load Control In the centralized load control approach we assume that the system operator co-optimizes the dispatch of flexible loads and generation resources: (EDω ) : min

XX (Kg ugt + Sg vgt + Cg pgt ) (7)

g∈G t∈T

s.t. X

pgt = Dωt + et , t ∈ T

(8)

g∈G

X

et = R

(9)

t∈T

0 ≤ et ≤ C, t ∈ T

(10)

? ? ugt = wgt , vgt = zgt , g ∈ Gs , t ∈ T

(11)

(p, e, u, v) ∈ D.

(12)

periods and a time-varying stochastic intercept that depends on the realization of inflexible demand. In order for the demand function model to be consistent with the two alternative demand response models, we calibrate the demand function parameters so that they satisfy the following two conditions: the demand functions have to yield a total daily demand of R subject to the charging rate constraint C, and the demand functions have to be consistent with the observed inflexible demand in the system. The calibration process is summarized in the following steps: Step (a). Select the fraction of inflexible demand α such that R represents a fraction 1 − α of total daily demand. In particular, given R, the fraction α for each day type is R ¯ determined as 1 − α = R+ ¯ , where D is the average daily D firm demand for each day type, as estimated from the available data. Step (b). Set the slope b such that the supply to priceresponsive consumers equals R in the economic dispatch model with slow generator schedules fixed according to the ? ? optimal solution wgt , zgt of (SU C). In particular, we proceed ¯ by fixing the demand functions at the point (λR , Dαt ) and calibrating the demand function slope b until the deterministic unit commitment model corresponding to an average wind ¯ ¯ power supply profile results in a total demand D α . Here Dt corresponds to the average hourly firm demand forP each day ¯ = ¯ type as estimated from the available data, and D t∈T Dt . Step (c). For each realization ω resulting in inflexible demand αQt (λR ; ω), set at (ω) = Qt (λR ; ω) + bλR in order to be consistent with the observed inflexible demand. Step (d). The inverse demand function for deferrable deqt mand is given by Bt (qt ; ω) = 1b (at (ω) − 1−α ), qt ≤ C. We can then discretize the inverse demand function to obtain valuations Blt for the set of price-responsive loads L and include these valuations in a welfare maximization formulation of the economic dispatch model: XX (EDω ) : max Blt dlt l∈L t∈T XX − (Kg ugt + Sg vgt + Cg pgt )

Despite the fact that the centralized model is not realistic in practice, it is useful for providing a benchmark for the potential benefits of demand flexibility. In this formulation, Dωt represents the net of firm demand minus renewable supply.

g∈G t∈T

s.t. X

pgt = Dωt +

g∈G

X

dlt , t ∈ T

(15)

l∈L

0≤

B. Demand Bids

X

dlt ≤ C, t ∈ T

(16)

l∈L

The demand model that we present in this section is based on Borenstein and Holland [9] and Joskow and Tirole [10], [11]. We assume a linear demand function that consists of a fraction α of inflexible consumers who face a fixed retail price λR , and a fraction 1 − α of price-responsive consumers who face the real-time price of electricity λt . The demand function Qt (·) for each period can therefore be expressed as: Qt (λt ; ω) = at (ω) − αbλR − (1 − α)bλt ,

(14)

(13)

where at (ω) is the intercept and b is the slope of the demand function. Note that we assume a common slope for all time

? ? ugt = wgt , vgt = zgt , g ∈ Gs , t ∈ T

(17)

(p, e, u, v) ∈ D,

(18)

where dlt represents the power draw of load segment l in period t. As in the case of the centralized demand response model in Section III-A, Dωt represents the net of firm demand minus renewable supply. C. Coupling Here we consider a contractual arrangement for coupling renewable suppliers with deferrable loads. According to such

6

a contract, an aggregator is entitled to any amount of output from a large group of renewable generation assets up to its loading capability. The aggregator then enters into a contractual agreement to supply deferrable loads. Loads are characterized by a fixed amount of energy demand within a fixed time window. The aggregator controls the loads directly and uses renewable resources as the primary energy source for satisfying deferrable demand. In the case of renewable supply shortage, the aggregator resorts (to a limited extent) to the real-time wholesale market for procuring power at the prevailing price. The aggregator compensates deferrable loads at a rate ρ for each unit of unserved energy. The setup is similar to dynamic scheduling [15], whereby demand and supply resources from different control areas pair their schedules in order to produce a zero net output to the remaining system. Such scheduling is currently implemented in the ERCOT market. For practical purposes we do not envision the load aggregator as becoming a trader of renewable power. We therefore assume that the aggregator has the option to consume renewable energy but not ownership over the renewable energy output. The aggregator can then schedule as much load as it has against the renewable supply but has no title against the residual. Effectively, the aggregator is holding a “use it or lose it” contract for the renewable supply output. 1) Implementation: As Schweppe et al. [13] discuss, the operating cost benefits of incorporating demand flexibility in power systems are expected to be outweighed by the savings in capital investment on balancing generation capacity. Such savings can be ensured, in the context of coupling contracts, by limiting the participation of aggregators in the real-time wholesale market. It is therefore necessary to provide financial incentives to deferrable loads for limiting their consumption to an efficient level that ensures the satisfaction of their demand while not imposing excessive capacity requirements on the system. Priority pricing introduced by Chao, Wilson, Oren and Smith [37], [38] and the derivative idea of callable forward contracts introduced by Gedra and Varaiya [39], and extended by Oren [40] can be used for limiting the participation of deferrable loads in the real-time market, while compensating loads for the capacity savings they enable. Callable forward contracts bundle a forward contract on power supply with a call option that can be exercised by the system operator in real time in order to limit the consumption of deferrable loads whenever real-time price exceeds a strike price k. Callable forward contracts therefore enable flexible consumers to enter the merit order stack of the system operator at the price k, which translates to capacity savings for the system operator. It is important to ensure that callable forward contracts, or other mechanisms for inducing deferrable loads to limit the degree of their participation in real-time markets, induce loads to self-select the degree of their participation in the realtime market efficiently. In particular, it is desirable to provide strong financial incentives for loads to limit their participation in the real-time market to the greatest possible extent, without however making these financial incentives so strong as to distort allocative efficiency. In the context of callable forward contracts, this translates to inducing loads to self-select the

lowest strike price k that still provides sufficient flexibility for deferrable loads to participate in the real-time market in order to satisfy their entire demand. 2) Problem Formulation: The coupling contract that we described in the previous section can be formulated as a stochastic optimal control problem. The aggregator solves the following: min E[

µt (xt )

X

λt (µt (xt ) − wt )+ ∆t + ρrN ], (19)

t∈T

s.t. r1 = R

(20)

µt (xt ) − wt ≤ Mt

(21)

0 ≤ µt (xt ) ≤ C

(22)

where µt (xt ) represents the rate at which power is supplied to deferrable loads. The state vector xt = (λt , wt , rt ) consists of the real-time price λt , the available renewable power supply wt and the remaining energy demand of the deferrable consumers rt . The initial condition for the residual demand is r1 = R, where R is the amount of energy demand to be satisfied. The control µt (xt ) is constrained by the rate of supply C and by the amount of energy that can be procured in the real-time electricity market Mt , which is a random variable. The rate of supply C is the same as the rate of deferrable loads that appears in Eq. (4). Hence, we obtain the constraints of Eqs. (21), (22). Unsatisfied energy incurs a penalty ρ. As we explain in the appendix, the limit on realtime market participation Mt depends on the choice of strike price. The optimal control problem stated above is solved by backward dynamic programming, with a lattice representing the state space of the stochastic processes. The lattice model of renewable power supply and real-time prices is presented in Section III-C3. 3) Lattice Models: Recombinant lattices are used for controlling the rate of growth of the dynamic programming lattice. Due to the fact that the state space of the optimal control problem of Eq. (19) includes residual energy demand, we need to limit the size of the state space for the stochastic state variables, in order to solve the problem using the dynamic programming algorithm. Therefore, although it is well known that wind power production and load (and therefore real-time prices) exhibit significant autocorrelation [31], [32], [41], [33], we will simplify the stochastic models of wind power and realtime prices by representing them as first-order autoregressive processes in order to control the size of the state space. Specifically, we assume that wind speed and real-time prices are driven by two correlated mean-reverting processes: Xt+1 Yt+1

√ (23) = Xt + κλ (θλ − Xt )∆t + σλ ∆tω1 √ = Yt + κw (θw − Yt )∆t + σλw σw ∆tω1 + q √ 2 )σ (1 − σλw (24) w ∆tω2 ,

where Xt and Yt are the noise terms of the price and wind models respectively, ω1 and ω2 are independent standard normal random variables, θλ and θw represent the average

7

trends of the price and wind noise respectively, the variance terms σλ and σw capture the effect of random shocks, κλ and κw model the rate at which the processes return to their mean value and σλw is a correlation coefficient that couples the evolution of the two processes. In our study we employ a discrete model that approximates the model of Equations (23), (24). The model is presented in Deng and Oren [42]. The dynamics of the process are given by:

 q √ 3  X + σ  λ  t 2 ∆t, j = 1 j Xt , j=2 Xt+1 = q √    Xt − σλ 3 ∆t, j = 3 2 q  p √ ∆t 2 )σ  3σ + 1 − σ Y + (  λw w t λw 2 , j =1  p √ j 2 2 j=2 Yt − σw 1 − σλw √2 ∆t, Yt+1 = q  p √   Y − ( 3σ − 1 − σ 2 )σ ∆t t λw λw w 2 , j = 3. (25) where Xtj and Ytj are the noise terms of the discrete price and wind models respectively and ∆t is the discretization interval. Each state j is visited with a probability pj that depends on the current state. The transition probabilities are defined in Fig. 3. Probability distribution function of real-time electricity prices (up) [42]. The lattice grows as O(n2 ), which enables us to control and wind power production (down). the growth rate and therefore the running time of the dynamic programming algorithm. XX The real-time price and wind speed values that are used (ED ) : min (Kg ugt + Sg vgt + Cg pgt ) ω in the stochastic optimal control problem of Eq. 19 can be (28) g∈G t∈T recovered by using the underlying noise and the systematic s.t. patterns of the underlying data, as explained in [36]: X pgt = Dωt , t ∈ T (29) g∈G

λt

=

wt

=

µ ˆλt + σ ˆtλ Fˆλ−1 (N (Xtj )), µ ˆw ˆtw Fˆw−1 (N (Ytj )). t +σ

(26)

? ? , g ∈ Gs , t ∈ T , vgt = zgt ugt = wgt

(30)

(p, u, v) ∈ D.

(31)

(27) IV. R ESULTS

Here µ ˆλt and σ ˆtλ represent the hourly mean and standard deviation of real-time prices for each day type respectively, as estimated from the available data. The inverse of the nonparametric distribution of the original data set is denoted as Fˆλ−1 and N (·) indicates the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution. The notation is analogous for the wind speed production process. Wind power is converted is converted to wind speed through a static aggregate power curve, as the authors describe in detail in [34]. The fit of the model to the data is presented in Fig. 3. 4) Incorporating the Coupling Model in Economic Dispatch: For any given realization of uncertainty ω, the solution of the optimal control problem of Section III-C2 induces a net demand profile µt (xt ) − wt for deferrable loads coupled with renewable resources. The total demand Dωt in the system is the sum of this net demand profile and the inflexible demand, as in Fig. 1. The resulting total demand is satisfied by the system operator in the economic dispatch phase:

We present results for a case study based on a reduced model of the Western Electricity Coordinating Council (WECC), also used in other studies [43], [7], [8]. The model consists of 124 generators. The average load in the system is 27298 MW, with a minimum of 18412 MW and a peak of 45562 MW. The net load profile that needs to be served by thermal generators and wind power, the generation mix of the system and a schematic of the WECC model are presented in Papavasiliou and Oren [8]. The entire thermal generation capacity of the system is 28381.5 MW. Thermal units with a capacity greater than 300 MW are classified as slow generators. There are 82 fast thermal generators with a total capacity of 9156.1 MW and 42 slow thermal generators with a total capacity of 19225.4 MW. The value of lost load is set to 5000 $/MWh. We use import, hydroelectric, geothermal and biomass production data from Yu et al. [43] that correspond to 2004. Since we are using 2004 import data, we also use load data from the same year, which is publicly available at the California

8

TABLE I PARAMETERS OF THE DEMAND RESPONSE CASE STUDY.

Wind capacity (MW) DR Capacity C (MW) Daily wind energy (MWh) Daily DR energy R (MWh) Flexible/firm demand (%)

No Wind 0 0 0 0 0

Moderate 6688 5000 46485 40000 6.1

Deep 14143 10000 95414 80000 12.2

ISO Oasis database. We use a retail price of λR = 130 $/MWh for the calibration of the demand function model, according to data provided by the U.S. Energy Information Administration [44]. The three wind integration cases that we consider are summarized in Table I. The load represented in Table I appears as additional flexible load in the system, as opposed to replacing existing load. For each level of wind integration, we assume a demand response integration level that is approximately one-for-one in terms of energy demand and capacity. We assume that deferrable requests span 24 hours, from midnight to midnight. This implies that the optimal control problem of Eq. (19) is solved for a 24-hour horizon from midnight to midnight. Analogously, the time horizon of the constraints in Eqs. (3), (9), span 24 hours, from midnight to midnight. We consider 6 levels of power supply for the control problem. The penalty of unserved energy is ρ = 5000 $/MWh. We use 12 scenarios for the formulation of the stochastic unit commitment model. The wind data that is used for the calibration of the statistical models is based on the National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL) 2006 Western Wind and Solar Integration Study [45]. The moderate and deep wind integration studies correspond to the 2012 and 2020 wind integration targets of California. We consider one day type for each season and in addition we differentiate between weekdays and weekends.

TABLE II S TRIKE PRICE THRESHOLD FOR DEFERRABLE LOAD CALLABLE FORWARD CONTRACTS ($/MW H ).

WinterWD SpringWD SummerWD FallWD WinterWE SpringWE SummerWE FallWE

Moderate 45 45 49 49 45 45 48 49

Deep 47 49 53 54 45 47 51 52

TABLE III DAILY COST OF OPERATIONS AND LOAD SHEDDING FOR EACH DAY TYPE NO WIND .

WinterWD SpringWD SummerWD FallWD WinterWE SpringWE SummerWE FallWE Total

Daily Cost ($) 7,390,206 7,145,737 13,684,880 9,589,506 6,079,003 5,855,883 11,839,573 7,868,146 9,012,031

Shed (MWh) 0.001 4.317 30.869 0 0.001 0 0 154.285 17.301

TABLE IV DAILY COST OF OPERATIONS FOR EACH DAY TYPE - MODERATE INTEGRATION .

WinterWD SpringWD SummerWD FallWD WinterWE SpringWE SummerWE FallWE Total relative (%)

Cost ($) Centralized 7,320,620 6,408,355 13,625,136 9,640,017 5,890,755 3,637,240 11,739,177 7,735,502 8,677,857

∆ Cost ($) Coupled 256,740 172,006 155,096 316,089 300,701 707,223 176,230 277,817 265,128 3.06

∆ Cost ($) Bids 300,051 139,589 219,124 157,159 246,408 244,353 234,101 189,465 211,010 2.43

A. Costs, Load Loss, Capacity Requirements and Spillage As we discuss in Section III-C1, deferrable demand can produce great economic value by limiting the requirements for balancing capacity. Callable forward contracts can be used for limiting the extent to which deferrable loads participate in the real-time market. The strike price of the callable forward contracts determines the extent to which loads can participate in the market. As the strike price of the contracts decreases, the participation of loads in the real-time market is increasingly limited. The strike price that mobilizes deferrable demand to the greatest possible extent is presented in Table II for each of the day types for each integration study. In order to obtain these strike price thresholds, we have gradually decreased the strike price of the stochastic optimal control of Eq. (19). As we explain in the appendix, as the strike price decreases the procurement margin and the ability of the aggregator to serve deferrable demand decreases as well. Below a certain strike price threshold, the aggregator cannot serve the entire amount of deferrable demand under all possible realizations of uncertainty. This is the threshold reported in Table II. In order to simplify the analysis, we assume a common strike price for each hour of the day.

In table III we present the operating costs and daily load losses for the case with no wind and no demand response in the system. These costs P consist of minimum load, startup and fuel costs, namely g∈G,t∈T (Kg ugt + Sg vgt + Cg pgt ). The operating costs do not include the cost of lost load. In Tables IV, VI we present the daily operating cost of each policy for the moderate and deep integration cases respectively. As in the case of Table III, these costs consist of minimum load, startup and fuel costs. The column with bold figures, that corresponds to centralized load dispatch by the system operator, represents absolute cost values. Cost figures corresponding to the other policies are relative to the centralized operating costs. The row with total costs weighs the cost of each day type with its relative frequency in the year in order to yield annual results. The last row shows the relative performance of centralized control with respect to the other policies, normalized by the cost of centralized control. Note that the operating costs of demand-side bidding outperform those of the coupling mechanism. This can be attributed to the diversification benefits of including flexible demand in the market.

9

TABLE V DAILY LOAD LOSS FOR EACH DAY TYPE - MODERATE INTEGRATION .

WinterWD SpringWD SummerWD FallWD WinterWE SpringWE SummerWE FallWE Total

Shed (MWh) Centralized 0 1.532 3.617 1.661 0 0 0.059 6.792 1.705

Shed (MWh) Coupled 0 1.869 4.346 1.661 0 0.249 1.100 10.005 2.217

Shed (MWh) Bids 177.257 701.828 821.719 799.323 642.105 453.791 215.816 976.766 609.914

TABLE VI DAILY COST OF OPERATIONS FOR EACH DAY TYPE FOR THE DEMAND RESPONSE STUDY - DEEP INTEGRATION .

WinterWD SpringWD SummerWD FallWD WinterWE SpringWE SummerWE FallWE Total relative (%)

Cost ($) Centralized 6,656,665 5,692,860 13,661,862 9,321,281 5,220,109 4,251,600 12,136,223 7,930,823 8,419,322

∆ Cost ($) Coupled 633,164 978,182 505,869 772,659 711,882 910,253 329,929 700,205 705,497 8.38

∆ Cost ($) Bids 556,775 572,465 835,609 404,523 616,931 576,010 472,930 515,431 578,909 6.88

TABLE VII DAILY LOAD LOSS FOR EACH DAY TYPE FOR THE DEMAND RESPONSE STUDY - DEEP INTEGRATION .

WinterWD SpringWD SummerWD FallWD WinterWE SpringWE SummerWE FallWE Total

Shed (MWh) Centralized 0.001 0 0.001 33.660 0 0 2.081 57.005 10.231

Shed (MWh) Coupled 8.290 351.782 36.643 143.629 0 32.601 58.725 132.134 112.452

Shed (MWh) Bids 552.769 1382.459 1952.332 1210.443 929.960 1008.222 1157.565 1260.137 1221.492

The ‘cost of anarchy’ that results from using price signals in order to control load response, rather than centralized control, ranges from 2.43% - 6.88% for the case of demand-side bidding and 3.06% - 8.38% in the case of coupling. Although demand bids result in lower operating costs, demand-side bidding results in excessive load shedding. This is due to the failure of demand bids to capture the inter-temporal dependencies of deferrable demand. Instead, the centralized dispatch model accounts for such inter-temporal dependencies in Eq. (9), while the deferrable demand model accounts for such dependencies through the initial conditions of the system expressed in Eq. (20). Note that the lost load presented in Table V accounts for the shortfall of power supply to deferrable loads throughout the entire day from the daily target demand R. In Table VIII we present a breakdown of operating costs by type for each of the demand response policies that we consider for each integration level. We note that the demandside bidding and coupling models result in cost increases in all cost categories. In Table IX we present the amount of capacity that is

TABLE VIII B REAKDOWN OF DAILY OPERATING COSTS FOR EACH DEMAND RESPONSE POLICY FOR EACH INTEGRATION LEVEL ($).

No wind Centralized Moderate Bids Moderate Coupled Moderate Centralized Deep Bids Deep Coupled Deep

Min load 1,382,156 1,246,552 1,317,383 1,330,130 1,194,606 1,360,543 1,432,948

Fuel 7,549,491 7,364,815 7,471,363 7,532,898 7,174,611 7,494,472 7,592,595

Startup 80,384 66,489 100,123 79,958 50,105 143,217 99,276

Total 9,098,537 8,677,857 8,888,866 8,942,958 8,419,322 8,998,232 9,124,819

TABLE IX C APACITY REQUIREMENTS AND WIND POWER SPILLAGE FOR EACH DEMAND RESPONSE POLICY.

No wind Moderate Deep

Capacity (MW) 26,123 26,254 26,789

Spillage (MWh) N/A 0 2

committed by each policy as well as the amount of renewable supply spillage. Capacity requirements do not change significantly for each integration study, which suggests that the additional deferrable demand can be fully absorbed by the installed renewable capacity. Wind spillage is negligible across all cases. B. Computational Details The stochastic unit commitment algorithm was implemented in AMPL. The mixed integer programs were solved with CPLEX 11.0.0 on a DELL Poweredge 1850 server (Intel Xeon 3.4 GHz, 1GB RAM). The Lagrangian relaxation algorithm that was used for solving the problem, which is presented in detail by Papavasiliou et al. [7], was run for 80 iterations, where the first 40 iterations were run without seeking for a feasible solution and the latter 40 iterations were run with feasibility recovery. The average elapsed time for this entire process was 7,047 seconds. The average duality gap U B−LB LB was 0.8%. Note that if a MIP gap  is used for the computation of the lower bound, then this gap should also be accounted for. In our case study we used a MIP gap of  = 1%. The average bound on the optimality gap, when also accounting for the MIP gap, is then computed as U B−(1−)LB = 1.81%. (1−)LB V. C ONCLUSIONS In this paper we present a stochastic unit commitment model that accounts for the large-scale integration of renewable energy sources and demand response resources. We consider three types of load response in our analysis, centralized load dispatch, demand-side bidding and coupling. We analyze the case of no wind in the network, as well as cases of wind integration that correspond to the 2012 and 2020 wind integration targets of California, with a corresponding one-forone increase in flexible demand. Our analysis is performed on a model of the Western Electricity Coordinating Council that consists of 124 generators. We find that the ‘cost of anarchy’ incurred by decentralizing demand response ranges between 3.06% - 8.38% for the case of coupling. Demandside bidding outperforms coupling with respect to operating

10

costs, resulting in a cost increase ranging between 2.43% - 6.88% of the cost corresponding to centralized load dispatch. However, demand-side bidding fails to capture the cross-elasticity of demand across time periods, resulting in excessive load losses. Arguably, if we assume that customers may adjust their response to avoid unserved load the price response functions should have been calibrated to reflect such behavior rather than matching expected energy served. In that case one would expect that cost would rise and unserved load decline, making the coupling strategy more competitive from a cost perspective. The ‘cost of anarchy’ imposed by coupling renewable resources with deferrable demand is the price for overcoming the institutional and regulatory barriers associated with the large-scale integration of demand response [30] that can in turn facilitate the large-scale integration of renewable resources. For the case studies that we consider, the additional integration of deferrable demand imposes no additional capacity requirements to the system. Renewable supply capacity is adequate for satisfying the added demand, which represents 6.1% - 12.2% of firm power demand for the 2012 and 2020 renewable integration targets respectively. The waste of available renewable power supply is negligible for the demand response integration study.

Fig. 4. The computation of the procurement margin Mt for Eq. 21 of the aggregator stochastic optimal control problem.

A PPENDIX

P1 represents the conventional capacity that is available up to marginal cost k. Total system load consists of net inflexible demand P2 (which is equal to inflexible demand minus imports minus non-wind renewable resources) plus deferrable demand. Therefore, the procurement margin of the aggregator is computed as Mt = P1 − P2 .

A. Notation for the Stochastic Unit Commitment and Economic Dispatch Problems

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

In this section we introduce the notation that is used in the unit commitment and economic dispatch models. Sets G: set of all generators, Gs : subset of slow generators L: set of load segments S: set of scenarios T : set of time periods Decision variables ugst : commitment, vgst : startup, pgst : production of generator g in scenario s, period t wgt : commitment, zgt : startup of slow generator g in period t est : supply to deferrable loads in scenario s, period t dlt : power draw of load segment l in period t Parameters πs : probability of scenario s Kg : minimum load cost, Sg : startup cost, Cg : marginal cost of generator g R: total energy energy demand, C: power rating of deferrable loads Dst : demand in scenario s, period t Blt : benefit of load segment l in period t B. Procurement Margin in the Aggregator Optimal Control Problem The computation of the margin Mt of Eq. (21) is explained in Fig. 4. The figure displays the merit order curve of the system. Given a strike price k, the megawatt capacity that corresponds to the given strike price is computed by inverting the merit order curve of the system. The resulting capacity

This research was funded by NSF Grant IIP 0969016, the US Department of Energy through a grant administered by the Consortium for Electric Reliability Technology Solutions (CERTS), the Power Systems Engineering Research Center, the Lawrence Livermore National Laboratory and the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission. R EFERENCES [1] P. A. Ruiz, R. C. Philbrick, and P. W. Sauer, “Wind power day-ahead uncertainty management through stochastic UC policies,” in Power Systems Conference and Exposition, March 2009, pp. 1–9. [2] R. Sioshansi and W. Short, “Evaluating the impacts of real time pricing on the usage of wind power generation,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 24, no. 2, pp. 516–524, May 2009. [3] J. Wang, M. Shahidehpour, and Z. Li, “Security-constrained unit commitment with volatile wind power generation,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 23, no. 3, pp. 1319–1327, August 2008. [4] E. M. Constantinescu, V. M. Zavala, M. Rocklin, S. Lee, and M. Anitescu, “A computational framework for uncertainty quantification and stochastic optimization in unit commitment with wind power generation,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 26, no. 1, pp. 431–441, February 2011. [5] A. Tuohy, P. Meibom, E. Denny, and M. O’Malley, “Unit commitment for systems with high wind penetration,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 24, no. 2, pp. 592–601, May 2009. [6] J. M. Morales, A. J. Conejo, and J. Perez-Ruiz, “Economic valuation of reserves in power systems with high penetration of wind power,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 24, no. 2, pp. 900–910, May 2009. [7] A. Papavasiliou, S. S. Oren, and R. P. O’Neill, “Reserve requirements for wind power integration: A scenario-based stochastic programming framework,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 26, no. 4, pp. 2197–2206, November 2011. [8] A. Papavasiliou and S. S. Oren. (2011) Multi-area stochastic unit commitment for high wind penetration in a transmission constrained network. [Online]. Available: http://www3.decf.berkeley.edu/∼tonypap/ ScenGenTransReview1Distr Redacted.pdf

11

[9] S. Borenstein and S. Holland, “On the efficiency of competitive electricity markets with time-invariant retail prices,” RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 36, no. 3, pp. 469–493, Autumn 2005. [10] P. Joskow and J. Tirole, “Retail electricity competition,” RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 37, no. 4, pp. 799–815, Winter 2006. [11] ——, “Reliability and competitive electricity markets,” RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 60–84, Spring 2007. [12] R. Sioshansi, “Modeling the impacts of electricity tariffs on plug-in hybrid electric vehicle charging, costs and emissions,” submitted to Operations Research, 2011. [13] F. C. Schweppe, M. C. Caramanis, R. D. Tabors, and R. E. Bohn, Spot Pricing of Electricity. Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1988. [14] S. Borenstein, M. Jaske, and A. Rosenfeld, “Dynamic pricing, advanced metering and demand response in electricity markets,” University of California Energy Institute, Tech. Rep., October 2002. [15] E. Hirst and B. Kirby, “Ancillary-service details: Dynamic scheduling,” Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Tech. Rep., January 1997. [16] B. Kirby, “Spinning reserve from responsive loads,” Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Tech. Rep., March 2003. [17] J. Eto, “Demand response spinning reserve demonstration,” Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, Tech. Rep., May 2007. [18] J. W. Lamont and S. Rajan, “Strategic bidding in an energy brokerage,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 12, no. 4, pp. 1729–1733, November 1997. [19] D. Zhang, Y. Wang, and P. B. Luh, “Optimization based bidding strategies in the deregulated market,” in Power Industry Computer Applications, July 1999, pp. 63–68. [20] A. K. David and F. Wen, “Strategic bidding in competitive electricity markets: a literature survey,” in Power Engineering Society Summer Meeting, vol. 4, 2000, pp. 2168–2173. [21] A. Ehrenmann and Y. Smeers, Stochastic Equilibrium Models for Generation Capacity Expansion, ser. Stochastic Optimization Methods in Finance and Energy, International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, Part 2. Springer, 2011, vol. 163, pp. 273–310. [22] J. Dupacova, N. Gr¨owe-Kuska, and W. R¨omisch, “Scenario reduction in stochastic programming: An approach using probability metrics,” Math Programming, vol. 95, no. 3, pp. 493–511, 2003. [23] H. Heitsch and W. R¨omisch, “Scenario reduction algorithms in stochastic programming,” Computational Optimization and Applications, vol. 24, no. 2-3, pp. 187–206, 2003. [24] N. Gr¨owe-Kuska, K. C. Kiwiel, M. P. Nowak, W. Romisch, and I. Wegner, Decision Making Under Uncertainty: Energy and Power, ser. IMA Volumes in Mathematics and Its Applications. New York: Springer-Verlag, 2002, vol. 128, ch. Power Management in a HydroThermal System Under Uncertainty by Lagrangian Relaxation, pp. 39– 70. [25] S. Takriti, J. R. Birge, and E. Long, “A stochastic model for the unit commitment problem,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 11, no. 3, August 1996. [26] P. Carpentier, G. Cohen, J.-C. Culioli, and A. Renaud, “Stochastic optimization of unit commitment: a new decomposition framework,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 11, no. 2, pp. 1067–1073, May 1996. [27] M. P. Nowak and W. R¨omisch, “Stochastic lagrangian relaxation applied to power scheduling in a hydro-thermal system under uncertainty,” Annals of Operations Research, vol. 100, no. 1-4, pp. 251–272, 2000. [28] T. Shiina and J. R. Birge, “Stochastic unit commitment problem,” International Transactions on Operations Research, vol. 11, no. 95, pp. 19–32, 2004. [29] L. Wu, M. Shahidehpour, and T. Li, “Stochastic security-constrained unit commitment,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 22, no. 2, pp. 800–811, May 2007. [30] (2012, September). [Online]. Available: http://www.caiso.com/ Documents/Board%206)%20briefing%20on%20distributed%20energy% 20resources [31] B. G. Brown, R. W. Katz, and A. H. Murhpy, “Time series models to simulate and forecast wind speed and wind power,” Journal of Climate and Applied Meteorology, vol. 23, pp. 1184–1195, 1984. [32] J. L. Torres, A. Garcia, M. D. Blas, and A. D. Francisco, “Forecast of hourly wind speed with ARMA models in Navarre (Spain),” Solar Energy, vol. 79, no. 1, pp. 65–77, July 2005. [33] D. Callaway, “Sequential reliability forecasting for wind energy: Temperature dependence and probability distributions,” IEEE Transactions on Energy Conversion, vol. 25, pp. 577–585, June 2010. [34] A. Papavasiliou and S. S. Oren, “Stochastic modeling of multi-area wind production,” in 12th International Conference on Probabilistic Methods Applied to Power Systems, June 2012.

[35] H. Chao, S. P. Peck, S. S. Oren, and R. B. Wilson, “Flow-based transmission rights and congestion management,” The Electricity Journal, vol. 13, no. 8, pp. 38–58, October 2000. [36] A. Papavasiliou, “Coupling renewable energy supply with deferrable demand,” Ph.D. dissertation, U.C. Berkeley, October 2011. [37] H.-P. Chao and R. Wilson, “Priority service: Pricing, investment and market organization,” The American Economic Review, vol. 77, no. 5, pp. 899–916, December 1987. [38] S. S. Oren, S. Smith, and R. Wilson, “Multi-product pricing for electric power,” Energy Economics, vol. 9, no. 2, pp. 104–114, April 1987. [39] T. W. Gedra and P. P. Varaiya, “Markets and pricing for interruptible electric power,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 8, no. 1, pp. 122–128, February 1993. [40] S. S. Oren, “Integrating real and financial options in demand-side electricity contracts,” Decision Support Systems, vol. 30, no. 3, pp. 279– 288, January 2001. [41] J. M. Morales, R. Minguez, and A. J. Conejo, “A methodology to generate statistically dependent wind speed scenarios,” Applied Energy, vol. 87, pp. 843–855, 2010. [42] S. Deng and S. S. Oren, Applications of Stochastic Programming. MPS-SIAM Series on Optimization, 2005, ch. Valuation of Electricity Generation Capacity, pp. 655–667. [43] N.-P. Yu, C.-C. Liu, and J. Price, “Evaluation of market rules using a multi-agent system method,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 25, pp. 470–479, February 2010. [44] [Online]. Available: http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/california/ [45] R. Piwko, K. Clark, L. Freeman, G. Jordan, and N. Miller, “Western wind and solar integration study,” National Renewable Energy Laboratory, Tech. Rep., May 2010.

Anthony Papavasiliou is a post-doctoral researcher in the department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research (IEOR) at the University of California at Berkeley and a student member of the IEEE. He has received his BS degree in Electrical and Computer Engineering from the National Technical University of Athens and his PhD degree from the IEOR department of UC Berkeley. Anthony has served as a consultant for Pacific Gas and Electric and Sun Run and has interned at the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, the Palo Alto Research Center and the Energy, Economics and Environment Modelling Laboratory at the National Technical University of Athens.

Shmuel S. Oren holds a Ph.D. degrees in Engineering Economic Systems from Stanford University, Stanford, CA, (1972). He is a Professor of IEOR at the University of California at Berkeley and the Berkeley site director of the Power System Engineering Research Center (PSERC). He was an adviser to the Market Oversight Division of the PUCT, and to the Energy Division of the CPUC and is currently member of the CAISO Market Surveillance Committee. Dr. Oren is a Fellow of INFORMS and of the IEEE.

Suggest Documents