DSGE Models and the Financial Crisis

DSGE Models and the Financial Crisis Based On: QE 1 vs. 2 vs. 3... A Framework for Analyzing Large Scale Asset Purchases as a Monetary Policy Tool* ...
Author: Tyrone Franklin
2 downloads 0 Views 216KB Size
DSGE Models and the Financial Crisis

Based On: QE 1 vs. 2 vs. 3... A Framework for Analyzing Large Scale Asset Purchases as a Monetary Policy Tool*

Mark Gertler NYU October 2012 *Joint with Peter Karadi 0

Introduction

• Describe how DSGE models have been adapted to the crisis

• Concrete example: Incorporating Quantitative Easing (QE) — Illustrate usefulness of microfoundations

1

A Brief Digression on Macro-Modeling Philosophy • No single model useful for all purposes: — Preferred Approach: Use a "suite" models (e.g. Bank of England) • DSGE models occupy a middle ground between statistical and theoretical — Finding this middle ground involves art as well as science. • No single DSGE useful for all purposes — Adjust detail to question at hand • Tools existed to incorporate financial factors well before crisis (e.g BGG 1999) — Failure to anticipate need for these tools — Literature now rapidly adjusting

2

Modeling QE: background • Fed has introduced a variety of new policy tools. Response to: — Disruption of credit markets — The zero lower bound.

• Most visible new tool: Large Scale Asset Purchases (LSAPs - also known as "QE") — QE1: December 2008 (AMBS, Agency Debt, Gov’t Bonds) — QE2: October 2010 (Gov’t Bonds) — QE3: September 2012: (AMBS)

3

Modeling QE: background (con’t) • Evidence from QE1 and QE2 that LSAPs have reduced long rates and rate spreads — "Large" effect of QE1 (e.g Gagnon et.al.) — "Modest" effect of QE2 ∗ 600 bill govt bonds purchase ∼15 basis point drop in 10 yr rate • Larger "size-adjusted" effect of QE1 (so type of security purchased matters) — QE1 "size adjusted" ∼ 44 basis points (based on Gagnon et.al). — QE1 also reduced AMBS and mortgage spreads

4

Introduction (con’t) • Objective: Develop a unified framework for analyzing LSAPs • Perspective: LSAPs reflect central bank intermediation. — Like private banks, CB funds assets by issuing short term debt. — Interest-bearing bank reserves ≈ short term gov’t debt • Effectiveness of LSAPs depends on limits to arbitrage on private intermediation — CB bank advantage: can obtain funds elastically. — Type of security purchased matters (e.g. AMBS vs.gov’t bonds). 5

Introduction (con’t) • Alternative view: Imperfectly elastic household demand for long term securities — e.g Preferred habitat. — Asset supplies matter.

• However, behavior of the marginal investor is key — Leveraged financial institutions are natural marginal investors. — Limits to arbitrage are key.

6

Table 1: Asset holdings of leveraged and non-leveraged institutions

Total Mortgages Agency MBS Treasuries & Agency debt Treasuries

Domestic net assets (Billions,$) all leveraged non-lev’d 14336 6170 8166 3590 1567 2023

% leveraged 43.0% 43.6%

non-lev’d 57.0% 56.4%

4195

1325

2870

31.6%

68.4%

1876

312

1563

16.7%

83.3%

Source: Flow of Funds, 2008 december Leveraged institutions: Commercial Banks, Savings Banks, Credit Unions, Brokers and Dealers, Government Sponsored Enterprises, Finance Companies Agency debt and Agency MBS is not published separately for different financial intermediaries. We assume each are held proportionally to their combined holdings by leveraged and non-leveraged institutions.

Macro Model • Baseline: Streamlined version of quantitative model widely used at central banks. — We keep: habit formation, investment adjustment costs, price rigidities. — We omit: wage rigidity, indexing, and variable factor utilization.

• Distinctive Features: — Banks (face endogenous financial constraints) — Central bank: conducts both LSAPs and conventional interest rate policy.

7

Households • Within each household, 1 −  "workers" and  "bankers". — Workers earn wages — Bankers manage financial intermediaries and pay dividends

• Perfect consumption insurance within the family. • Bankers have finite expected horizons 1 ) — With i.i.d prob. 1 − , a banker exits next period. (Expected horizon = 1−

— Replaced by new bankers who receive a start-up transfer from the family. 8

CAPITAL PRODUCERS

NONFINANCIAL FIRMS



Dh Q Sp

q Bp GOVERNMENT

  

HOUSEHOLDS

N

Banks • Balance Sheet  +  =  + 

• Net worth   = −1−1 + −1−1 − −1 with

 =

 +   ; −1

 =

1 +  −1

9

Banks (con’t) Objective  = {Λ+1[(1 − ) +1 + +1]

with

 = ( − )−1−1 + ( − )−1−1 + −1

Λ+1 ≡ household’s stochastic discount factor

10

Banks (con’t) • With Frictionless Capital Markets Λ+1+1 = Λ+1+1 = Λ+1+1

• With Capital Market Frictions

Λ+1+1 ≥ Λ+1+1

Λ+1+1 ≥ Λ+1+1 11

Limits to Bank Arbitrage • Agency Problem: After the banker/intermediary borrows funds at the end of period  it may divert: — a fraction of  of loans — a fraction and ∆ of gov’t bonds, with 0 ≤ ∆ ≤ 1. • If the bank does not honor its debt, creditors can recover the residual funds and shut the bank down. ⇒ • Incentive constraint  ≥  + ∆ 12

Bank Optimization Problem: Solution • Balance sheet constraint  + ∆ ≤   ≡ maximum "adjusted" leverage ratio: Depends positively on excess returns • Arbitrage e e Λ +1(+1 − +1) = ∆Λ+1(+1 − +1)

13

Aggregation • Aggregate leverage constraint  + ∆ ≤ 

• Aggregate net worth  = [( − )−1−1 + ( − )−1−1 + −1] + 

14

LSAPs • Central bank intermediation supplements private intermediation:  +  = 

• The central bank issues government debt  that pays +1 and then buys private securities and government bonds at market prices • Central bank less efficient at intermediating securities than private banks — cost of   per unit for private securities;   for gov’t bonds. • Unlike private intermediaries, the central bank is not "balance-sheet" constrained. 15

LSAPs (con’t) • Total asset demands  =  +   =  +  =⇒ • Effects of LSAPs on total private securities demand:  ≤  − ∆ + ( + ∆)

Since ∆  1 per dollar,  has a weaker effect on asset demand than 

16

CAPITAL PRODUCERS

NONFINANCIAL FIRMS



  

Dh Q Sp

q Bp

HOUSEHOLDS

N

GOVERNMENT

Q Sg q Bg

Dg

Direct Household Asset Holdings • Households can directly hold  and  subject to proportional holding costs: — Private securities: 12 ( −  )2 for  ≥   — Gov’t bonds: 12 ( −  )2 for  ≥   • Household asset demands Λ+1(+1 − +1)  =   +  Λ+1(+1 − +1)  =   + 

17

LSAPs Direct Hh Asset Holdings • Composition of Asset Holdings  =  +  +   =  +  + 

• Private Security Demands with LSAPs ( − ) ≤  +  + ∆[ − ( − )]

• Qualitative effects of LSAPs similar to baseline case — Relative strength depends inversely on Hh demand elasticities — For LSAPs to matter need limits to arbitrage for both Hh and banks 18

Non-financial Business Sector • Intermediate goods producers make output using capital and labor — Finance capital by issuing risky securities  at price 

 =  + (1 − ) • —  +1 ≡ shock to "capital quality." ⇒ +1 =  +1[ + (1 − )]

• Capital producers sell new capital at the price  • Retailers sell final output; set nominal prices on a staggered basis. 19

Government Budget Constraint and Monetary Policy • Government Budget Constraint

 + ( − 1) =  + ( − )−1−1 + ( − )−1−1

• Monetary Policy — Interest rate rule  =  +    +  (log  − log ∗) +  — LSAPs  =   =  20

CB purchases %∆ from ss

% of GDP

2 1 0

0

20

40

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

0

−1

0

R %∆ from ss

0 −2

0

20

40

−1

1 0

0

40

20

40

−1

1

4

20

0

2

10

−1

0

0

−2

0

20

40

−10

0

ib10

20

40

−3

0.2

0.2

0

−0.1

0.1

0.1

−0.5

−0.2

0

0

−1

−0.3

−0.1

−0.1

20 Quarters

40

−0.4

0

20 Quarters

40

Private asset purchase

−0.2

0

20 Quarters

40

20

40

ik10−ib10

0

0

0

ib10−ii10

0.5

−1.5

20 E[Rk]−R

30

−2

0

N

6

E[Rb]−R %∆ from ss

20

i 2

Q

2

−4

π

Y

3

40

−0.2

0

20 Quarters

40

Government bond purchase

Figure 1: Private and government asset purchase shocks. Purchases are calibrated to a peak effect of 2.5% of GDP and interest rates are kept unchanged for 4 periods.

2.5

1

2 1.5

0.8

2 1.5 1

0.6

1

0.4

0.5

0.2

0.5 0

π

Y 1.2

%∆ from ss

% of GDP

Shocks 3

0

0 0

20

40

−0.2

0

20

40

0

ib10

i 1

20

40

ik10−ib10

0

0.02

0.8

0 −0.05

0.6 %∆ from ss

−0.5

−0.02

0.4

−0.04 −0.1

0.2

−0.06

0

−0.08

−0.15

−0.2 −0.4

−0.1 0

20 Quarters

40

−0.2

0

20 Quarters

Government bond purchase

40

−0.12

0

20 Quarters

40

Monetary policy shock

Figure 2: Monetary and government bond purchase shocks. The government bond purchase shock is calibrated to a peak effect of 2.5% of GDP with interest rates kept unchanged for 4 periods. The monetary policy shock reduces the nominal interest rate by 40 basis-points below its steady state value for 4 periods.

2.5

1

1.5

1

0.8

2 1.5 1

0.6 0.5 0.4 0.2

0.5 0

π

Y 1.2

%∆ from ss

% of GDP

CB purchases 3

0

0 0

20

40

−0.2

0

20

40

−0.5

0

ib10

i 1

20

40

ik10−ib10

0.05

0.02 0

%∆ from ss

0 0.5

−0.02 −0.05

−0.04

0

−0.06 −0.1 −0.08

−0.5

0

20 Quarters

40

−0.15

0

20 Quarters

No interest rate response

40

−0.1

0

20 Quarters

40

Interest rate response

Figure 3: Government bond purchase shocks with and without interest rate responses. The bond policy is calibrated to a peak effect of 2.5% of GDP. The interest rate is kept unchanged for 4 periods.

2.5

1

1.5 1

1

0.6 0.5 0.4 0.2

0.5

0

0 0

20

40

−0.2

0

20

40

−0.5

20

40

ik10−ib10

1

0

0.02

0.8

−0.02

0

−0.04

−0.02

−0.06

−0.04

−0.08

−0.06

−0.1

−0.08

0.6

0

ib10

i

%∆ from ss

1.5

0.8

2

0

π

Y 1.2

%∆ from ss

% of GDP

CB purchases 3

0.4 0.2 0 −0.2 −0.4

0

−0.12 20 40 0 20 Quarters Quarters Not segmented HH asset markets

40

−0.1

0

20 Quarters Segmented HH asset markets

40

Figure 4: Government bond purchase shocks with and without segmented household asset markets. Purchases are calibrated to a peak effect of 2.5% of GDP and interest rates are kept unchanged for 4 periods.



4 2

0

−2

−5

0 −5

−3 0

20

40

−10

0

R

20

40

−10

−2 0

Q

4 %∆ from ss

i

5

20

40

−4

20

40

E[R ]−R k

0

20

0

−50

10

−10

−100

0

2

0

N

10

0 −2 −4

0

20

40

−20

0

E[Rb]−R

20

40

−150

0

ib10−ii10

10

20

40

1

20 Quarters

40

No policy

0

0

20 Quarters

40

0

40

8

0.5 0

20 Purchases

3 2

0

0

ik10−ib10

1

5

−5

−10

% of GDP

%∆ from ss

0

−1

−4

%∆ from ss

π

Y

0

0

Private asset purchase

20 Quarters

40

6 4 2 0

0

20 Quarters

40

Government bond purchase

Figure 5: Crisis experiment. Reactions to two consecutive unexpected capital quality shocks with gradual private and government asset purchases with the zero-lower bound.

Purchases

π

Y

7 6

4

5

3

4

%∆ from ss

% of GDP

5 4 3

3 2 2 1 1

2 0

1 0

0

20

40

−1

0 0

20

−1

40

ib10

i 4

0

2

%∆ from ss

%∆ from ss

−0.1

−0.2

0 −0.3

20 Quarters

−0.2

−0.4 20 40 0 20 Quarters Quarters Private asset purchase Government bond purchase 40

−0.4

−0.1

−0.3

−1 0

40

0.1

3

−2

20

ik10−ib10

0

1

0

0

40

Figure 6: Effects of private and government asset purchases following the crisis experiment. The figures plot the differences from a no-policy-response case.

Concluding Remarks • LSAPS reflect CB intermediation and not "money creation" per se. — Effective if limits to arbitrage in private financial intermediation • Like conventional policy, LSAPs stimulate the economy by reducing credit costs — Transmission to real output and inflation very similar — Unlike conventional policy, effective at the ZLB • Variations of LSAPs fit within our framework — "Sterilzed" QE — LTROs (by the ECB) • DSGE models can be adapted to meet current needs of central bankers! 21