FALL 2009



RESEARCH PUBLICATION / SUSTAINABILITY

24-Hour Cities Part 1 of 3

24-Hour Cities and Office Rent Performance A research report prepared for the Steven L. Newman Real Estate Institute, Baruch College, CUNY by contributing author Hugh F. Kelly, CRE, Clinical Associate Professor of the Schack Real Estate Institute, New York University.

F

or more than a decade, it has been asserted that “24hour cities” outperform “9to-5 cities” for investors in commercial real estate. Since

1995, the widely-read survey of Emerging Trends in Real Estate1 has proposed that traditional market distinctions such as the comparison of central business districts (CBDs) to suburbs matter far less than the capacity of places to sustain activity well beyond the bounds of the traditional business day. Yet this claim, though often discussed, has never been rigorously examined. Though there are a number of investments firms that speak about programs of investing in 24-hour locations, a search of the academic and the industry literature failed to uncover any studies that took a serious and detailed look at the numbers that might support or refute the 24-hour city hypothesis.

Its assertions reflect the judgments of

hours. The cities included in each of the

an influential panel of experts. Given

proposed clusters are:

the wide circulation of the report, and its reputation in the U.S. commercial property industry, its claims can help to shape the outlook for this sector. The

This paper and two others to follow

‘principle of anticipation’ holds that the

attempt to bring together for the first

value of an asset is equal to the anticipated

time the component elements that

future benefits of ownership. Hence, any

would

quantitative

information such as the Emerging Trends

analysis of those claims, and the investor

report that helps articulate expectations

expectations they presumably reflect.

should be carefully examined.

permit

a

sound

Emerging Trends develops its annual report by a broad survey of hundreds of

developers,

investors,

lenders,

consultants, analysts, academics, and others

with

high-level

professional

interest in commercial property. The annual publication, therefore, represents the combined perspectives gleaned from the interviewing process, as interpreted by the report’s authors and editors.

This paper focuses on office rents for a hypothesized set of 24-hour cites, and a complementary set of 9-to-5 cities. Where data is available, information on the individual cities will be discussed, but the burden of the analysis will be carried by the groups of cities considered reflective of 24-hour status, versus those regarded as generally more tied to limited business

P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

24-hour markets

9-to-5 markets

Boston

Atlanta

Chicago

Dallas

Las Vegas

Los Angeles

Miami

Minneapolis

New York

Philadelphia

San Francisco

Phoenix

Washington, D.C.

Seattle

In each cluster, I have selected those cities most frequently mentioned by Emerging Trends, but added other cities (Miami and Las Vegas in the 24-hour group, Minneapolis and Seattle in the 9-to-5 group) that may fall somewhere 1 Emerging

Trends was originally a project of the Real Estate Research Corporation, and was co-published by the Equitable Life Assurance Society of the United States. It has experienced changing sponsorship over the years, and is now co-published by the Urban Land Institute and PricewaterhouseCoopers.

24-HOUR CITIES

FALL 2009

framework, as Kuhn (1962) described in his influential work, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. The A-M-M model, in common with most economic equilibrium approaches, is grounded in Newtonian principles of physics and mechanics. Those fundamental sciences have, in the 20th century, advanced to accommodate stochastic elements unknown to Newton and are now pursued as

quantum

physics

and

quantum

mechanics. The still-powerful explanatory power of A-M-M as a theoretical model is confirmed by the evident tendency of most U.S. cities to sprawl outward and the persistent evidence that commercial, as well as residential, land uses grow away from the center in the majority of in between the two paradigmatic types.

become devalued vis-à-vis new sub-

U.S. metropolitan areas. This can be

The added cities serve to add some

centers, that should be manifested in

seen as an example of economic entropy

balance, too: bringing to the 24-hour

differential land rents. Changes in those

across the intrametropolitan, as well as

group some Sunbelt exposure, and

differential land rents would indicate if

the intermetropolitan geography of the

adding some coastal markets to the 9-to-

the value of agglomeration economies

United States.

5 grouping.

is

Theoretical considerations

appropriate measure of agglomeration economies, namely differential land rent between intense clusters of economic activity, such as the central business (CBD)

and

sub-centers

(the

death

of

distance

of the information economy in urban

Urban economic theory points to the

districts

falling

hypothesis), or rising (the expansion

of

metropolitan areas. In the monocentric city model canonically developed by Alonso, Mills, and Muth (A-M-M), land rents are highest in the CBD and then fall off with distance from the center. From the mid-twentieth century forward, the monocentric city model became less descriptive of actual metropolitan areas, as transportation and communication costs fell and the production of goods dispersed from urban centers. Sub-centers or ‘edge cities’ sprang up around cities. If the urban center has

centers hypothesis).

Researchers in complexity theory have been seeking to model elements of emergent

self-organization

against

the background of entropy posited by

During the 1980s and 1990s, the

Newton’s Second Law. This approach has

polycentric

character

promise both for understanding economic

of many U.S. metro areas becomes

clustering in multi-nodal cities and for

apparent. The stress such urban trends

24-hour downtowns as well. The work of

placed upon the A-M-M model was

Bettencourt, et al., (2007), which discerns

recognized by many investigators. By

differences in the ‘metabolism’ of cities,

1993, Mills himself had conceded that

namely their capacity to turn resources

the generality of the Alonso-Mills-Muth

into economic and social energy, may be

model could no longer be asserted as

an early example of the usefulness of this

a tenable proposition. Yet the power of

approach.

or

multinodal

2

the model can be seen by its continued use as a point of departure long after

Historical Rent and Vacancy Data

this concession. For many metro areas,

The empirical basis for this paper is

A-M-M still serves as an adequate

commercial office rents in major office

approximation of urban spatial trends.

markets of the United States. The

Far from rejecting the value of the model, exceptions prompt a search for

P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

a

more

inclusive

–2–

theoretical

See works by Greene, 1980; LeRoy and Sonstelie, 1983; Steen, 1986; Gin and Sonstelie, 1992; White, 1994; Baum-Snow and Kahn, 2005; Glaeser, Kahn and Rappaport, 2008 as cited in the bibliography. 2

24-HOUR CITIES

FALL 2009

theoretical link between land rents

research strategy for that paper was the disaggregation of the markets by size and by

and office rents is strong, and data on

concentration.

office rents is more readily available. The sample is derived from 122 major office markets in 52 MSAs over 21 years (19872007) in a database maintained by Torto Wheaton Research.

This analysis uses

data drawn from the sample, analyzing variation in real rents and occupancy. This paper does not develop and estimate here a multi-equation model seeking to regress the relevant variables of real estate markets. That is an objective of a larger project now underway. Nor does it examine the risk-adjusted returns and their impact on capital flows, themes that will be explored in subsequent papers in this series. The present focus is to use real office rents (expressed in constant 2007 U.S. dollars) and vacancy rates in many metropolitan

For purposes of analysis, data generously supplied by Torto Wheaton Research was segmented into four classes of commercial office markets.

The 49 markets with

complete data sets were sorted into four analytical groups, defined below, and listed in Table 1. The aggregate volume of these markets is 3.46 billion square feet of net rentable area, an average of just over 70 million square feet per market. The mean ratio of downtown space to total in the sample is 33.79%. I. Primary, Strong Core Markets are those above the sample mean for both the size of the metro market and the ratio of downtown space to total. Seven markets comprise this subset. II. Primary, Weak Core Markets are those above the mean in market size, but below the mean of downtown space as a percent of total inventory. There are six markets in this subset. III. Secondary Markets are those having between 35 and 70 million square feet of inventory. In the table below, the secondary markets having more than 33.8% of total in their downtowns are indicated by an asterisk (*). Sixteen markets are designated as “secondary”.

Table 1: Table 1

Markets by Analytical GroupingMarkets

by Analytical Grouping

markets over time to determine if the

Primary, Strong Core

Primary, Weak Core

Secondary

Tertiary

asserted superiority of 24-hour markets

Boston

Atlanta

Baltimore

Albuquerque

can be observed in the data series

Chicago

Dallas

Charlotte*

Austin

New York

Denver

Cleveland*

Cincinnati*

Philadelphia

Detroit

Kansas City

Columbus*

San Francisco

Houston

Miami

Ft. Lauderdale

that producer services activities tend

Seattle

Los Angeles

Minneapolis*

Ft. Worth

to cluster in large metropolitan areas

Washington, DC

Newark*

Hartford

(Drennan 2002), the paper explores the

Oakland*

Honolulu*

question as to whether central locations

Orange County, CA

Indianapolis*

command a premium over alternative

Phoenix

Jacksonville*

locations in the same urban area. If

Portland*

Las Vegas

Sacramento

Nashville

San Diego

Orlando

This paper builds upon work previously

San Jose

Riverside

co-authored with Matthew P. Drennan

St. Louis

Salt Lake City

of UCLA, now out for peer review

Tampa

Stamford*

normally used to measure real estate performance. Further, given the view that urban agglomeration economies decay with distance (Acs 2003) and

so, have such premiums increased, decreased, or disappeared?

(Drennan-Kelly, 2009). That research

Trenton

pointed to steady or enhanced real

Tucson

rents in some markets (expansion of the

West Palm Beach

information economy) and real declines

Wilmington

in other markets. A key element in the Source: Drennan-Kelly forthcoming Source: Drennan-Kelly (2009),(2009), forthcoming

P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

–3–

0 19 19 19 19 19 24-HOUR CITIES 8 9 9 9 8 8

7

IV. Tertiary Markets are those with less than 35 million square feet of office space. The remaining twenty markets

99

97

24-hour CBD Vacancy

Figure 1:

19

19

5

3

1

20

01

20

03

20

05

2FALL 00 7

2009

24-hour Suburbs Vacancy

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Full Sample of Markets $30

are included in this category. Tertiary markets whose downtowns comprise

$29

more than 33.8% of total inventory are

$28

indicated by an asterisk (*).

$27 $26

Table 1 has been slightly modified from

$25

its original form in Drennan-Kelly, by

$24

noting 24-hour markets in bold italic

$23

font, and 9-to-5 comparison markets in

$22

bold.

$21 $20

The hypothesized set of 24-hour markets

19

differs somewhat from the Drennan-

87

19

19

19

19

88

19

19

95

93

91

20

99

97

01

20

03

20

20

05

07

Kelly clustering of ‘strong-core, primary 24-hour city grouping includes Boston,

Suburbs

CBD

markets.’ The cluster considered in the

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Chicago, Las Vegas, Miami, New York, San Francisco, and Washington, D.C.

$12 per square foot, a narrower range than the primary strong core cluster. The reason for

Five of these are classified “strong

the difference is in higher suburban rents surrounding the 24-hour downtowns, suggesting

core, primary” in the Drennan-Kelly

a positive regional influence from 24-hour activity.

categorization. Miami is a secondary market, and Las Vegas a tertiary market.

Over the 21-year timeframe reviewed, real rents in 24-hour city downtowns have commanded a 28.8% premium over their adjacent suburbs (Figure 2). That rental premium

The presence of five markets common

has expanded sharply since 2000, and stood at 41% as the fourth quarter 2007. The

to each group yields the unsurprising

premium was at a low of 14% in 1997, but has been between 20% and 29.9% in twelve of

result that summary data for the ‘strong

the 21 years, between 30% and 39.9% in six of the years, and above 40% in 2006 and 2007.

core primary’ markets and the ’24-hour

Real rents surged most strongly in the late 1990s, coincident with the tech boom, but also

city’ markets are extremely similar. Both

reflecting the long and quite robust overall job expansion that characterized the national

clusters show substantially higher rents

economy toward the end of the last century. From 1987 to 2007, real rents grew most

than the average level of all U.S. markets. This is true within the CBDs and for the suburbs as well. The rent premium for

Figure 2

Figure 2:

For Set of 24-hour Cities, Downtown Rents Average 28.8% Higher their Respective Suburbs For Set of 24-hour Cities, Downtown Rentsthan Average 28.8% Higher than their Respective Suburbs

CBDs in both clusters is quite obvious, especially at market peaks.

50

Rents, in constant 2007 dollars per square foot

45

Drennan-Kelly found virtually no rent

40

premium discernable for downtowns

35

across the entire sample of MSAs provided by Torto Wheaton (Figure

30

1). The difference was only one or

25

two dollars per square foot (constant

20 19

2007 US$). For the primary strong core

87

markets, the differential ranges between

88

19

91

19

93

19

95

24-hour CBD Rents

$5 and $17 per square foot. The 24-hour city cluster registers a differential of $6 to

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

24-hour Suburbs Rents

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

19

–4–

20

07

Suburban R

28.8% Higher than their Respective Suburbs

Rents, in constant 2007 dollars per square

24-HOUR CITIES 50

FALL 2009

35

Rents, in constant 2007 dollars per square foot

30

45 strongly in the Manhattan office market

two decade time span averaged 2.42%

vacancy rate for 24-hour downtowns was

40 and showed gains in Las Vegas, San

lower than for the surrounding suburban

9.2 percentage25points, compared with

Francisco, and Washington’s downtowns 35

office markets. Not only were the

as well. For suburban markets in 2430

suburban markets more volatile than

12.5 percentage20points for the suburbs.

hour metros, Las Vegas, Miami, and 25

the 24-hour downtowns (with a standard

San Francisco posted gains in inflation-

deviation for their vacancy rates of

20

adjusted rents between 1987 and 19 19 19 2007. 19 88

87

95

93

91

4.08% 2.80% for 20 the 20 CBDs), 1vs. 20 19 20 but the 9

19

Over that period, 24-hour CBDs tended

03

01

05

07

variation was greatest at the upper end 24-hour Suburbs range Rents with a peak 19.7% of the vacancy

24-hour CBD Rents to have higher occupancy rates than

their

99

97

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton analysis by Hugh Kelly suburbs. Vacancies for Research; the 24-hour metro markets,

associated

and a

(Figure 3) were much less volatile in 24-

15.5% peak for the downtowns as a

hour downtowns, and over the roughly

group. The range of the mean annual

By contrast, performance in the 9-to15 5 cluster of markets is remarkably homogeneous

10

when 1

19downtown 19 is 19 19 88 95 93 91

98

7

compared to suburb. Since 1993, in

CBD Rents fact, suburbs have maintained a9-to-5 modest

premium over CBD rents, although this is

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Whe

not as dramatic as Drennan-Kelly found for ‘weak core primary markets.’ The likely reason is that two of the 9-to-5 markets posited for this study are Philadelphia

Figure 3: For Set of 24-hour Cities, Vacancy Average 242 basis points lower than their For SetDowntown of 24-hour Cities, Downtown Vacancy Average Respective Suburbs

242 basis points lower than their Respective Suburbs

25

F

and Seattle, both of which in thea 11 9-to-5 Suburbs Haveare Posted Drennan-Kelly ‘strong core primary’ in Most Dramatically

Figure 3

group. Furthermore, Minneapolis is a Vancancy Rate in Percent

secondary 25 market by size, but has a

Vacancy Rate, in percent

strong

CBD

inventory

concentration

20

20

at 45.6% of total MSA office space. All three of these market display real rents 15

15

that are, on average, very similar for their

10

downtowns10and their suburbs. For the seven posited 9-to-5 metros, a slim 0.5%

5

5

average real rent premium is measured in

0 19

19

19

88

87

91

19

93

19

19

19

95

24-hour CBD Vacancy

20

20

99

97

20

03

01

20

05

07

favor of the0suburbs (Figure 4), dwarfed 19 earned 19 19 by CBDs 19 by the 28.8% premium 8 9 9 8 8

7

19

95

3

1

in the 24-hour metro cluster. The 9-to-5

24-hour Suburbs Vacancy

9-to-5 CBD Vacancy markets failed to regain their prior peak

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

of real rents in the market cycle which

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton

reached its acme in 2000, and real rents in

$30

Figure 4: $29

2007 were 27.8% lower for 9-to-5 CBDs

Figure 4

$28 In 9-to-5 Metros, Very Little Difference in CBD In 9-to-5 Metros, Very Little Difference in CBD and Suburban Rents Overtime

Suburban Rents Overtime

$27 $26

Rental for 24-hou when compared with Premium 1987. For suburbs,

and

$12decades for CBDs the decline in realaveraged rents over two was about half as much – 13.9%, but still

Rents, in constant 2007 dollars per square foot

Rents, in constant 2007 dollars per squa

35

seriously lagging 25 the 24-hour city cluster.

$24

30

Only Seattle showed a gain in real rents 20

$23

25

15 managed to do so both in its downtown

20

and suburbs. Dallas’ downtown had the 10

$25

$22 $21 $20

between 1987 and 2007, and this market

most alarming drop in real rents over the

15

5

19

1 10 987

19

88

19

87

19

88

91 19 91

19

93 19 93

19

95

19

95 CBD

19

97

19

19

99

19

99 97 Suburbs

9-to-5 CBD Rents

01

20

03

20

05

9-to-5 Suburbs Rents

07

20

07

0

19 19a 1had The suburban 9-to-5198 markets 99 8 9 7

8

1

116 basis point advantage in average

3

1

Suburbs occupancy, consisting mostly differential in their

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

period, more than 50%.

20

05

03

01

20

20

20

20

–5–

descent to single-digit vacancy in the

Source: Data courtesy of Torto W

Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

24-HOUR CITIES

1996 – 1998 period. Throughout the 1990s, in fact, the suburbs boasted

Figure 3

higher occupancies than the downtowns , Downtown Vacancy Average the Respective 9-to-5 cluster of metro areas han in their Suburbs

FALL 2009

Figure 5:

Figure 5

Have 116 Basis Point Occupancy Advantage, 9-to-59-to-5 SuburbsSuburbs Have Posted a 116 Posted Basis PointaOccupancy Advantage, Most Dramatically in the 1992-1998 Period Most Dramatically in the 1992-1998 Period

(Figure 5). The vacancy rate range over

25

the period is smaller for the CBDs of the 9-to-5 group, at 9.87 percentage

Vancancy Rate in Percent

20

points, than the range for the associated 15

suburbs, at 13.84 percentage points. Yet both peaked at just above 22%

10

vacancy, the suburbs in the final years of the 1980s and the CBDs in 1993.

5

Since 2000, however, the CBD/suburb 1

19

2

2

2

0

2

00 00has been 99 0differential 00 01 97 occupancy very 3 5 9 7

markets when compared with 9-to-5 markets, when downtowns are matched with downtowns and suburbs with suburbs. The 24-hour downtowns have

e Difference in CBD and registered real rent premiums ranging ts Overtime

97

19

93

19

95

19

19

20

20

20

99

97

20

05

03

01

07

9-to-5 Suburbs Vacancy

9-to-5 CBD Vacancy

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Figure 6: Figure 6

Rental Premium for Premium 24-hour markets 9-to-5 markets has over averaged $12 for CBDs andhas $4 for Rental for over 24-hour markets 9-to-5 markets Suburbs since 1987

averaged $12 for CBDs and $4 for Suburbs since 1987

between $8.15 per square foot (in 1991, at the trough of the Savings and Loan

20

foot (in 2000, just before the bursting of the dot-com bubble). Much of the

15

spike in 2000, in fact, is due to the sharp 19

10

rental1 rise in2 the San Francisco area, with 2 2

97

99

00

00

00

Rents, in constant 2007 dollars per square foot

25

industry collapse) to $22.40 per square

20

07 5 3 and venture 9 1 its high-technology capital

5

concentration, and in New York, where Suburbs

0

20 20 1the 20 market was surging to a cyclical 20 99 stock 03 05 01 07 9

19

19

19

88

87

high-water mark. Over the 21 annual

9-to-5 Suburbs Rents

observations, the average premium for

24-hour CBDs has been n Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

5

91

positive real

rental differential earned by 24-hour

4

19

88

87

24-hour Suburbs Vacancy

Figure analysis 6 illustrates the ton Research; by Hugh Kelly

19

19

narrow for 9-to-5 metro markets.

91

19

93

19

19

95

97

differential Suburbs Rents

19

20

99

01

20

20

03

20

05

07

differential CBD Rents

$12.11 when

compared with 9-to-5 downtowns. The

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

advantage does appear to carry over to the suburbs, but in a much attenuated

low point in the premium for suburbs

fashion. (This is consistent with the

was in the early 1990s, but slightly later

attenuation findings asisagglomeration Point Occupancy Advantage, he 1992-1998 Period of Rosenthal and Strange, 2005a and

This is undoubtedly related to the comparative vacancies displayed in Figure

Figure 7

and for a bit longer period than CBDs the have 7. On thissignificantly graph, the negative Vacancy Rates in 24-hour been lower scope than of downtown lull. The suburbs of the 24-differential the y-axis the degree to which in 9-to-5 market; Suburban hasindicates decreased over time

2005b). The suburban rent premium

hour metros did not seem to partake

for 24-hour markets vis-à-vis the 9-to-5

of the 2003 – 2007 cyclical upturn in

than in 9-to-5 markets, a condition that

panel is $4.19 in real dollars, about 35%

anything like the robust response of the

describes then entire period with one

of the premium earned by the downtown

24-hour downtowns. 1

vacancies are lower in 24-hour markets

Vacnacy in 24-hour offiice Markets compared with 9-to-5 markets, in percent

1

24-hour panel. As with the CBDs, the P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

0

-1

19

87

98

8

-2 -3 -4

–6–

19

91

19

93

brief

19

95

19

exceptional

19

9

20

period:

20

0

20

0

suburban

20

97 3 5 lower07in 1996 9 rates01were slightly vacancy

24-HOUR CITIES Figure 6

Rental Premium for 24-hour markets over 9-to-5 markets has averaged $12 for CBDs and $4 for Suburbs since 1987

Taken together, the evidence appears fairly convincing that the hypothesized 24-hour

markets,

especially

their

downtowns, have posted superior results

Rents, in constant 2007 dollars per square foot

25

FALL 2009

in inflation-adjusted rents and in office market

20

occupancy,

when

compared

with the posited 9-to-5 metros. Within

15

24-hour metros, there is a clear rental pricing differential with higher prices

10

in the central business district. Though

5

cyclical softening affects this differential,

0

19

19

19

88

87

91

19

93

19

19

95

97

differential Suburbs Rents

19

99

20

20

20

03

01

it has not entirely disappeared at any of

20

05

07

the years reviewed. Moreover, since 1996 24-hour CBDs have been able to sustain

differential CBD Rents

higher occupancy rates than either their own suburban areas or the 9-to-5 metros’

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

downtowns and suburbs. The next task to is evaluate what, if any

Figure 7:

Figure 7

Vacancy Rates in 24-hour CBDs have been significantly lower than Vacancy Rates in 24-hour CBDs have been significantly lower than in 9-to-5 market; Suburban difmarket; Suburban differential has decreased over time ferentialin has9-to-5 decreased over time

effect, these superior supply and demand fundamentals have had on investment pricing and returns, and this will be the subject of the following paper in this

Vacnacy in 24-hour offiice Markets compared with 9-to-5 markets, in percent

series. ■

1 0 -1

19

87

19

88

19

91

19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

-2 -3

This research report is published by the Steven L. Newman Real Estate Institute, Baruch College, CUNY. The Newman Real Estate Institute gratefully acknowledges the support of the sponsors who make possible our efforts to promote critical thinking on topical issues for the real estate industry.

-4 -5 -6

The views expressed in the research report are those of the authors and not necessarily those of Baruch College, City University of New York, or any of its affiliated organizations, foundations, and sponsors.

-7 -8 differential Suburbs Vacancy

differential CBD Vacancy

Please address inquiries to Jack S. Nyman, Director, at:

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

Source: Data courtesy of Torto Wheaton Research; analysis by Hugh Kelly

and 1997 in the 9-to-5 markets. The

24-hour downtowns by 484 and 646 basis

sharply increasing rent differential for 24-

points. Over the same period, suburbs

hour downtowns (compared with 9-to-5

in 24-hour metros have never held an

downtowns) has fluctuated between

advantage of more than 368 basis points

$10 and $22 per square foot since 1996,

(in 2000), and have averaged just 106

(about the time of the early discussion

basis points of occupancy advantage

of 24-hour markets in Emerging Trends

over 9-to-5 metro suburbs in the 2001 –

in Real Estate), a period in which the

2007 time frame.

Tel: 646.660.6950 • Fax: 646.660.6951 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

Stan Altman, Interim President, Baruch College William Newman, Founding Chair Richard Pergolis, Co-Chair Jack S. Nyman, Director

occupancy rate advantage has favored P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

Baruch College, CUNY 137 East 22nd Street Box C-0120 New York, NY 10010

–7–

24-HOUR CITIES

FALL 2009

Bibliography Alonso,W., “Location and Land Use: Toward a General Theory of Land Rent,” Harvard University Press, 1964. Baum-Snow, N., and M.E. Kahn, “Effects of Urban Rail Transit Expansions: Evidence from Sixteen Cities: 1970 -2000,” Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs, 2005. Bettencourt, L.M.A., J. Lobo, D. Helbing, C. Kuhnert, and G.B. West, “Growth, Innovation, Scaling and the Pace of Life in Cities,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, April 24, 2007. Drennan, M.P. and H.F. Kelly, “Measuring Urban Agglomeration over Time with Office Rents,” (unpublished manuscript currently out for review), 2009. Gin, A., and J. Sonstelie, “The Streetcar and Residential Location in Nineteenth Century Philadelphia,” Journal of Urban Economics, Volume 32, 1992. Glaeser, E.L., M.E. Kahn, and J. Rappaport, “Why Do the Poor Live in Cities?,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper number 7636, April 2000. Greene, D.L., “Recent Trends in Urban Spatial Structure, Growth and Change,” January 1980. Kuhn, T.S., “The Structure of Scientific Revolutions,” University of Chicago Press, 1962. LeRoy, S.F. and J. Sonstelie, “Paradise Lost and Regained: Transportation Innovation, Income, and Residential Location,” Journal of Urban Economics, Volume 13, 1983. Mills, E.S., “An Aggregative Model of Resource Allocation in a Metropolitan Area,” American Economic Review, Volume 57, May 1967. Muth, R., “The Distribution of Population within Urban Areas,” Determinants of Investment Behavior, edited by Robert Ferber, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1967. Rosenthal, S.S. and W.C. Strange, “The Attenuation of Human Spillover Effects: The Manhattan Skyline Approach,” working paper, 2005. Rosenthal, S.S. and W.C. Strange, “The Geography of Entrepreneurship in the New York Metropolitan Area,” working paper, 2005. Steen, R.C., “Nonubiquitous Transportation and Urban Population Density Gradients,” Journal of Urban Economics, Volume 20, 1986. Torto Wheaton Research, Various data on office market rents, inventories, and vacancies, 1987- 2007. Urban Land Institute and Pricewaterhouse Coopers, “Emerging Trends in Real Estate,” Washington, D.C., Multiple Volumes, 1995 – 2008. White, M.J., “Housing and the Journey to Work in U.S. Cities, in Noguchi and Poterba,” Housing Markets in the United States and Japan, University of Chicago Press, 1984.

P: 646.660.6950 / 137 East 22nd Street, New York, NY 10010 www.baruch.cuny.edu/realestate

–8–