STRATEGY AND GAMES. Context and concepts. The field of strategy. Game theory

Context and concepts STRATEGY AND GAMES w Context: You’re in an industry with a small number of competitors. You’re concerned that if you cut your p...
Author: Morgan Farmer
40 downloads 0 Views 196KB Size
Context and concepts

STRATEGY AND GAMES

w Context: You’re in an industry with a small number of competitors. You’re concerned that if you cut your price, your competitors will, too. How do you act? Ditto pretty much any strategic decision: capacity, entry and exit, product positioning. w Concepts: players, strategies, dominant and dominated strategies, best responses, Nash equilibrium. w Example: E.T. Whether Mars should buy a product placement for M&Ms.

© 2001 Cabral and Backus (10/26/01)

The field of strategy

Game theory w Formal analysis of strategic behaviour: relations between inter-dependent agents.

w Strategy includes: w Organizational structure and processes needed to implement the firm’s plan w Boundaries of the firm: scale, scope, extent of outsourcing w Formal analysis of strategic behaviour: game theory

w Informally, game theory reminds us to w Understand our competitors. Our results depend not only on our own decisions but on our competitors’ decisions as well. w Look into the future. Decisions taken today may have an impact in future decisions, both by ourselves and by our competitors. w Pay attention to information. Who knows what can make a difference. w Look for win-win opportunities. Some situations are competitive, but others offer benefits to all.

What they say

Overview

I think it is instructive to use game theory analysis... Game theory forces you to see a business situation over many periods from two perspectives: yours and your competitor’s. — Judy Lewent, CFO, Merck At their worst, game theorists represent a throw back to the days of such whiz kids as Robert McNamara … who thought that rigorous analytical skills were the key to success. Managers have much to learn from game theory -provided they use it to clarify their thinking, not as a substitute for business experience. — The Economist

w Our goal is to create an awareness of strategic considerations in many circumstances of business life (and, in fact, of everyday life). w Our focus is on how to play some common games: pricing, capacity, entry and exit, product positioning, and ways to encourage cooperation. w In practice, many of the benefits come from choosing the right games and avoiding the wrong ones. For example: avoid price games.

1

Historical notes

The E.T. “chocolate wars” In the movie “E.T.” a trail of Reese's Pieces, one of Hershey's chocolate brands, is used to lure the little alien into the house. As a result of the publicity created by this scene, sales of Reese's Pieces tripled, allowing Hershey to catch up with rival Mars.

[JvN, also co-inventor of the computer/ operating system.]

John von Neuman, precursor of game theory.

The 1995 U.S. spectrum auction was partly designed by game theorist Paul Milgrom .

John Nash, 1994 Nobel laureate, the first game theorist to receive the prize. Game theory is now commonly used by various consulting companies such as McKinsey.

Chocolate wars… w Universal Studio's original plan was to use a trail of Mars‘s M&Ms and charge Mars $1mm for the product placement. w However, Mars turned down the offer, presumably because it thought $1mm was high. w The producers of “E.T.” then turned to Hershey, who accepted the deal, which turned out to be very favorable to them (and unfavorable to Mars).

Mars 1: decision approach

buy

Chocolate wars… w Formal analysis of the E.T. game. w Suppose: w Publicity from the product placement increases Mars‘s profits by $800,000. w Hershey's increase in market share costs Mars $500,000. w Benefit to Hershey from having its brand featured is given by b. w Hershey knows the value of b. Mars knows only that b=$1,200,000 or b=$700,000 with equal probability.

Mars 2: naïve game theory

[-200]

M

buy

[-200, 0]

M not buy

not buy [0]

0

buy

[-500, -50]

H not buy

[0, 0]

2

Mars 3: real game theory

Quick summary w Think about your competitor: Mars should think about Hershey, and vice versa.

[-200, 0]

buy

buy

-500

M

b = 1200 (50%) not buy

-250

[-500, 200]

H not buy

[0, 0]

N b = 700 (50%)

buy

0

[-500, -300]

w Timing matters: Hershey had the last move. w Information matters: Hershey has more information than Mars, and in this example it made a difference. w Key business insight: part of the benefit to Mars was to keep the opportunity from Hershey. Similar situation: Boeing, Airbus, and the super-jumbo.

H not buy

[0, 0]

Game theory: concepts

Normal-form game

w What are the elements of a game? w w w w

Player B

Players (in previous example: Mars and Hershey) Rules (sequentially respond to Universal’s offer) Strategies (Yes or No) Payoffs (sales minus payment to Universal)

w What can I do with it? w Determine how good each of my strategies is w Figure out what my rival is probably going to do

T

L

C

5

6

9

8 3

Player A

M 1 2

7 1

5 2

7 B

R

6 0

6 3

8 4

Moves are simultaneous. Which make sense?

Dominant/dominated strategies w Dominant strategy: payoff is greater than any other strategy regardless of rival’s choice. w Rule 1: if there is one, choose it.

w Dominated strategy: payoff is lower than some other strategy regardless of rival’s choice. w Rule 2: do not choose dominated strategies.

w Are there dominant or dominated strategies in the example?

Outcomes of games w Sometimes a game can be “solved” just by looking at dominant and dominated strategies (e.g., example above). w However, there are many games for which this isn’t enough to produce an outcome. à Nash equilibrium: Combination of moves in which no player would want to change her strategy unilaterally. Each chooses its best strategy given what the others are doing.

3

Prisoner’s dilemma

w Dominant strategies: high output.

Iraq’s Output

Example: output setting (million barrels a day) by OPEC members

Iran’s Output

Prisoner’s dilemma…

2

2

4

42

44

46

26 22

4

52

24 32

Takeaways

w Equilibrium payoffs are (32,24), much worse than would be attained by low output, (46,42). w Conflict between individual incentives and joint incentives. w Typical of many business situations. w Are cartels inherently unstable?

Practice problem 2.7

w Game theory is a formal approach to strategy. L

w Highlights impact of strategic interactions among firms or other “players.”

2 T

w Forces you to consider your competitors’ choices. Player 1

w More coming…

Player 2 C

1

1 1

M 2

2

2

Practice problem 2.8 Time/Newsweek cover story game

Time

Imp

Imp Crisis 35,35 70,30

Crisis

30,70

15,15

1 2

4 0

3 3

Imp Time

• Dominated strategy? • Best responses?

• Dominant strategy? • Dominated strategy? • Best responses?

Practice problem 2.8…

Questions: • Dominant strategy?

Questions:

• Nash equilibrium?

Version (ii): Time more popular Newsweek

Version (i): evenly matched Newsweek

1 1

2

B 10

R

0

Crisis

Questions: • Dominant strategy?

Imp

42,28 70,30

• Dominated strategy?

Crisis

30,70

• Best responses?

18,12

• Nash equilibrium? Version (iii): Some buy both

• Nash equilibrium? Time

Imp

Crisis

Imp

42,28

70,50

Crisis

50,70

30,20

Comment: This is a product positioning game. The question is whether to fight head-to-head or differentiate. Answer: It depends!

4

Ericsson v Nokia

Ericsson v Nokia…

w Ericsson and Nokia compete on 4G handsets. Two possible price levels: $100 and $90. Production cost is $40. Estimated market demand (000 per quarter):

w Suppose firms choose prices simultaneously. Describe the game and solve it.

Nokia’s price 100 90 800 100

900

90

900

Ericsson’s price

700

Estimated profit ($m per quarter):

Nokia’s price 100 90

1,100

48

400

Ericsonn’s price

900 *

800

Ericsson v Nokia… w Both Ericsson and Nokia have a dominant strategy: price at $90. The Nash equilibrium of this game is therefore (90,90), leading to profits of (40,45) for Ericsson and Nokia, respectively.

30m = (100-40) 500k

100

30*

90

45

42

w Suppose that Nokia has a limited capacity of 900k units per quarter. How would the analysis change? (Changes in yellow.) Estimated profit ($mm per quarter):

Nokia’s price 100 90 48 100

24 42

w Your CIO is unsure whether Nokia is capacity constrained or not. How much would you value this piece of info? How would your strategy depend on it?

36

45

90

w Suppose you work for Ericsson. Your market research team tells you that practically 100% of all unfulfilled demand for Nokia will be transferred to Ericsson.

45

30

Ericsson’s price

w It is now a dominant strategy for Nokia to price at $100. It is still a dominant strategy for Ericsson to price at $90.

45 40

Ericsson v Nokia 2

w Notice that both Ericsson and Nokia are worse off than they would be by pricing at $100. This game has the structure of a prisoner’s dilemma.

Ericsson v Nokia 2…

55 24

40

Coke v Pepsi w

You work for Pepsi. The company has just signed a major star endorsement. You must decide how much to spend on for your Summer ad campaign. Net profits (in $m) depend on how much you and Coke spend – and on whether or not Coke has signed a major star: Coke’s adv 2 1 3 Pepsi’s adv

2

0

1

1

Coke’s adv 2 1

2 1

4

5 2

(a) Coke signed major star

0 Pepsi’s adv

2

4

1

2

1 6

2

3 3

(b) Coke did not

5

Coke v Pepsi…

Coke v Pepsi intuition

w Coke’s decision of whether to sign a major star has already been taken. You don’t know what the decision was. Your CIO tells you that there is a 70% chance they did. w You also know that Coke will have a chance to react to your decision of how much to spend. w Should you go for a $1m or a $2m campaign?

w

This is a sequential game with incomplete information. Let us solve it backwards and include “Nature” as a player.

w

If Coke did sign a star, then it will choose $2m if and only if Pepsi chooses $2m. If Coke did not sign a star, then it will choose $1m regardless of what Pepsi chooses.

w

Moving backwards: w If Pepsi chooses $1m, then Coke will choose $1m. Pepsi’s expected payoff is 70% 2 + 30% 3 = $2.3m. w If Pepsi chooses $2m, then Coke will choose $2m with probability 70%, $1m with probability 30%. Pepsi’s expected payoff is 70% 0 + 30% 6 = $1.8m. w Pepsi should choose $1m. (What considerations are we leaving out of the analysis?)

Coke v Pepsi game tree P 70% 2 + + 30% 3 = 2.3

1

2

N

N

star (70%)

no star (80%)

C

70% 0 + + 30% 6 = 1.8

star

C

no star (80%)

C

C

1

2

1

2

1

2

1

2

2

1

3

2

1

0

6

4

5

4

3

2

2

3

1

0

6