STATIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

SØK/ECON 535 Imperfect Competition and Strategic Interaction STATIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Lecture notes 10.09.02 Nash Equilibrium Describes strategic inte...
Author: Stewart Wiggins
2 downloads 0 Views 145KB Size
SØK/ECON 535 Imperfect Competition and Strategic Interaction

STATIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Lecture notes 10.09.02 Nash Equilibrium Describes strategic interaction by equilibrium in non-cooperative games. Strategies: ai , i = 1,2,..., n . i Payoff (profit) functions: Π ( ai ; a− i ) .

Definition: a strategy combination (a * 1,...,a * n) constitutes a Nash equilibrium if, for i = 1,...,n, ∀ai : Π i (ai∗ , a−∗ i ) ≥ Π i (ai , a−∗ i ) The Cournot model (1838)

Strategies are quantities (supply/output): qi , i = 1,2,...n . Firms choose simultaneously (i.e. without knowing their competitors’ strategies). Duopoly (n = 2)

Homogeneous products. i Profit functions: Π ( qi , q j ) = P (Q ) qi − Ci ( qi ) ,Q = q1 + q2 , i = 1,2 .

Π i is assumed strictly concave and two times differentiable. FOC: P ′ (Q ) qi + P (Q ) − Ci′ ( qi ) = 0 Negative external effect on competitor’s profit P ′ (Q ) q j ; therefore producers choose a larger quantity than that which would maximise total profits: P (Q ) − Ci′ ( qi ) = −P ′ (Q ) qi < −P ′ (Q ) [q1 + q2 ] ⇒ Qd > Qm

Price is lower and output greater than in monopoly (perfect cartel).

At equilibrium, marginal costs are equal only if firms are symmetric; therefore, for given aggregate output, total costs are generally not minimised. From the FOC we obtain the Lerner index: Li ≡

P − Ci′ α i = P ε

where α i = qi Q is i’s market share and ε = −P ′ (Q ) Q P is the price elasticity of demand. i Reaction functions (from FOC): Π i (Ri (q j ),qj ) = 0. 1

Ri′ = −

Π iij Π iii

p j  where D ( p ) is market demand. Assume marginal costs are constant and identical (= c). Nash equilibrium: p1 = p2 = c . ( pi > p j cannot be an equilibrium because j can increase profits by raising price; pi = p j > c cannot be an equilibrium because either firm would want to undercut; pi = p j < c cannot be an equilibrium because either firm would want to raise its price.) Conclusion: duopoly equals perfect competition! In the case of asymmetric costs ( ci > c j ), the only equilibrium involves j obtaining a monopoly at price equal to the cost of i; that is, p j = pi (technical assumptions to guarantee existence. The "Bertrand Paradox"

Solutions to the paradox: product differentiation. 4

capacity constraints (Edgeworth); inter-temporal (dynamic) competition (threat of price wars); Product differentiation

Demand does not necessarily disappear even if price exceeds those of the competitors.

(

)

i Profit functions: π ( pi , p j ) = pi Di ( pi , p j ) − Ci Di ( pi , p j ) , i = 1,2.

π i assumed strictly concave and twice differentiable.

(

)

i Reaction functions (from first-order conditions): π i ri ( p j ) , p j = 0 .

ri′ = −

π iji >0 π iii

if marginal profit is increasing in competitor’s price. If so, prices are strategic complements.

Figure (equilibrium described by reaction functions) Price competition with capacity constraints

Example (costly capacity): Demand: D ( p ) = 1 − p Unit capacity costs: c ∈  34 ,1 Variable costs are constant and normalised to 0 Capacity constraints: qi ≤ qi , i = 1, 2 . Rationing

Assume p1 < p2 and D ( p1 ) > q1 : Who gets to buy from Firm 1? Efficient rationing: residual demand equals D ( p2 ) − q1 if D ( p1 ) > q1 , 0 otherwise. Two stage game 1)

Firms choose capacities simultaneously. 5

2)

Firms choose prices simultaneously. Trade takes place and profits are realised.

We are looking for a Subgame Perfect Equilibrium, in which, from each stage of the game, the strategies constitute a Nash equilibrium of the continuation game. Solves the game by backward induction. STAGE 2: Gross monopoly profits equal 1/4. Therefore, no firm will ever choose q > because that would lead to negative profits.

1 3

Given q ≤ 31 , i = 1, 2 , there exists a unique Nash equilibrium in which p1 = p2 = p* = 1 − q1 − q2 . Proof of existence: There is no point in reducing prices because capacity constraints bind. Profits for firm 1 when p1 > p2 = p * equals p1 [1 − p1 − q2 ] . The marginal profits is 1 − 2 p1 − q2 < 1 − 2 [1 − q1 − q2 ] − q2 = 2q1 + q2 − 1 ≤ 0.

STAGE 1: Reduced-form profit functions, given equilibrium play at Stage 2, are

[

]

Π i (q i , q j ) = 1 − q i − q j q i , i = 12 , . In other words, Cournot profits. Conclusion: The two-stage game leads to the same equilibrium outcome as in the Cournot model. The difference is that here prices are set by firms rather than by some Walrasian auctioneer or other equilibrating ‘mechanism’. Caveats: For larger capacities ( qi > 31 ), an equilibrium in pure strategies generally does not exist and one may have to consider mixed strategies (KrepsSheinkman, 1983). The equivalence with the Cournot model does not necessarily hold for other rationing rules (for example, proportional rationing, such that everyone with willingness to pay above the lowest price has equal probability of getting to buy at this price). 6

Institutional detail – pricing rules and capacity constraints

Market outcomes may depend on the finer details of market institutions; in particular, how firms are remunerated. Assume demand D is perfectly inelastic. There are two (symmetric) firms with capacities k and unit costs c. Firms set prices simultaneously: pi ∈ c, P  . A market price is set equal to the price of the marginal supplier; that is,

 min { p1, p2 } if D ≤ k P= max { p1, p2 } if D > k Low-demand periods ( D ≤ k )

There is a unique (Bertrand like) equilibrium in pure strategies in which p1 = p2 = c . High-demand periods ( D > k )

There are many equilibria, all having outcomes with one firm pricing at P and the other pricing so low as to avoid undercutting; that is, pi = P and p j = b ≥ c, bk ≤ P [D − k ] . Ref: N-H von der Fehr and D Harbord (1993): Spot market competition in the UK electricity industry, The Economic Journal, 103, 531-46. Under the Bertrand assumption (i.e. each firm being paid its own price) we would have the same equilibrium in low-demand periods, but in high-demand periods equilibria would be different; in particular, only mixed-strategy equilibria exists.

7