Multiple Margins of Fishing Behavior: Implications for Predicting the Effects of a Policy Change

Multiple Margins of Fishing Behavior: Implications for Predicting the Effects of a Policy Change Matthew Reimer University of Alaska Anchorage Instit...
Author: Tracey Tucker
1 downloads 0 Views 7MB Size
Multiple Margins of Fishing Behavior: Implications for Predicting the Effects of a Policy Change

Matthew Reimer University of Alaska Anchorage Institute of Social and Economic Research

Multiple Margins of Fishing Behavior • Fisheries management history: reactive policymaking - fishermen have far more flexibility than originally thought - new policies react to unanticipated consequences of previous policies • Example: BC Salmon Limited Entry Program 1969 •



Rapid erosion of effort controls as fishermen expanded into “free” effort dimensions.

Initial limits on number of vessels ➡ Limit on tonnage of vessels ➡ Limit on length of vessel ➡ Limit on gear types ➡ Limit on combining licenses

Ignoring behavioral margins = regulatory surprises • Traditional models of the fishing production process ignore the primary behavioral margins of fishermen !

- Early models: aggregate production functions relating industry catch to industry fishing effort !

- Powerful insights: e.g. open access = biological overexploitation + dissipation of rents (Gordon, 1954) !

- Interpretation: “too many boats chasing too few fish.” Fix incentives along this margin, and fisheries problem solved! !

- Accumulation of experience shows that other margins are likely to matter. !

“The New Fisheries Economics: Incentives Across Many Margins” M.D. Smith (2012)

• Multiple margins (extensive and intensive) across which fishermen act - amount of gear - fishing grounds - type of gear - product types - number of trips - fish size - trip length - entry or exit - target species - different fisheries !

• To what extent should managers control these margins? - How can managers control these margins? - What are the consequences of ignoring them? - How do we know ex ante what margins are important?

Fishery Production Models and Policy Invariance CONCEPTS

possibility curve could be drawn for each input level. Furthermore, w the combination of outputs that maximise profit, given an input level to that which maximises revenue.^ The revenue equivalent to the iso isorevenue line, which has slope equal to {-pxlpi), the negative rati prices. The optimal (revenue-maximising) point is determined b tangency between this line and the production possibility curve, Figure 3.2.

• Conventional aggregate fishery production models that ignore primary behavioral margins do not identify policy invariant parameters y2

92

• Catchability parameters and selectivity curves convey biological, technical, and behavioral relationships

Policy Invariant?

Pppc (x)ixrxio) ~ ~ " ~ ~ " ^ ^ / ^

0

y1 qi

The Importance of Policy Invariance: Lucas Critique (1976) • It is naïve to try to predict the outcome of a policy intervention entirely on the basis of a relationship that systematically alters with a change in policy.

• “Policy invariance facilitates the job of forecasting the impacts of interventions. If some parameters are invariant to policy changes, they can be safely transported to different policy environments.” (Heckman, 2010)

What are the implications of ignoring key behavioral margins when predicting the effects of a policy? Outline • Traditional approaches to modeling fishery production - How have these been used to predict policy interventions?

• Simulation exercise - How does a policy intervention change production relationships when accounting for behavioral margins?

• Empirical investigation of the Bering Sea groundfish fleet - Are empirical aggregate production relationships invariant to a policy change that changed fishermen incentives?

• Current and future directions - Implications for policy evaluation: where do we go from here?

A Pressing Question: Are Catch Shares Appropriate for Multispecies Fisheries? • Catch shares—a secure privilege to harvest a proportion of a fishery’s total allowable catch. - can be allocated for multiple species - can be allocated to individuals, groups, or communities - often seen as “the way” to end the “race-for-fish” under open access institutions

A Pressing Question: Are Catch Shares Appropriate for Multispecies Fisheries? • Can fishermen match their catch composition with a portfolio of quota allocations? - fishing gear is not perfectly selective (Squires et al. 1987) - could encourage illegal discarding and data fouling (Copes, 1986) - “choke” species and unharvested quota - selectivity depends on targeting ability (Pascoe et al. 2007)

• Targeting ability—or output substitution capabilities—can be represented via a multi-output production function - curvature of the production frontier indicates a fisherman’s “ability” to substitute between species

Output Substitutability with “Bad” Outputsb = und 0 ARTICLE IN PRESS

2. Directionalpossibility output distance function with desirable and u Figure 4.1:Fig. Production set example - Example R. Fa¨re et al. / Journaloutputs. of Econometrics 126 (2005) 469–492 Adapted from F¨are et al. (2005). y = desirable output

g = (gy, -gb)

This idea is made for output the general case of byproducts in Murty b = clearly undesirable null jointness and weak disposability assumptions are a reduced form wa This function seeks through theoutputs. simultaneous maximum reducti Directional output distance function with and desirable undesirable between good badand outputs abatement e↵orts that are not exp 0

Fig. 2.

(q/p) researchers have modeled environmental out well. Some outputs areofeffectively treated as isinputs with to similar strong Satisfaction conditions (i)-(vi) sufficient express the which would yield an unbounded output set; for examples the use of aand transformation function T (McFadden, 1978): outp Hailu Veeman (2001). However, an unbounded Output Set : possible if traditional inputs are given. (y + Although β*gy, b - β*gb) our set representations P (x) = {(y,ofb)the : Ttechnology (x, y, b) are 0} ,c are not very helpful from a computational viewpoint. He representations of technology, which allow us to mainta where T (x, y, b) = 0 represents the production possibilities fron accommodate thePWproduction of byproducts, and are consis (x) Our preferred modeloutput is the that directional output set ofapproach. all combinations of “efficient” can be obtained g¼ 3 ðgy ; gb Þ be a directional vector (illustrated below), puts directional x. The production transformation function T (·) provides a F = (b, y) distance function is defined as relation that represents the multidimensional set of feasible o ~o ðx; y; b; gy ; $gb Þ ¼ maxfb : ðy þ bgy ; b $ bgb Þ 2 PðxÞ D 2

3

expansion in good outputs. Fig. 2 illustrates the directional o

A Pressing Question: Are Catch Shares Appropriate for Multispecies Fisheries? • Data from non-catch shares fisheries suggest catch shares face serious challenges due to weak substitution possibilities between species - e.g. Squires (1987); Squires and Kirkley (1991,1995,1996); Pascoe et al. (2007,2010)

• Evidence from multispecies catch shares shows greater flexibility than previously thought - e.g. Branch and Hilborn (2008); Sanchirico et al. (2006)

• Perhaps output substitution revealed through ex ante empirical investigations reveal more about behavior and incentives than actual technical relationships.

Neglected Margins of Production

Fishing production depends on temporal and spatial choices.....

Multispecies production function: microfoundations local  production y = y1 y2 function:

x y2

global production function

10000

y

x2 x3

4000

x4

6000

v2

x1

✓1jt ✓2jt

8000

X

=



y1 0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

Simulation Model T wo Species : bycatch(1) and target(2)

(a) bycatch(1)

(a)

(b)

25

25

25 10

25

25

3000

3000

3000

10

30

1600

9

9

2700

2700

2700

27 1400

8

8

20

2400

(b)

7 6

2100

5

3000 1800

15 4 3

20

20

target(2)

(c)

bycatch(1) 20

2400

1200 1 1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

2400 900

10

600

5

2100

15

15

15

1800

1800

6

21

160015

10

1200

10

10

15

20

25

0 1800

10

1200

140010

20 900

5

600

5

300

15 5

10

15 5

2010

2515

20

25

5

0

1

25

0

5 200

5

10

15

5

20

25

6

7

8

9

10

90

400

60

1000 10

600

300

20

4

200

400

15

3

5

900 600

2

1200

800 10

12

600

300

0

15

2

900

600

5

18

800

1

1500 1200

1000 4 3

1500

1500

300

5

1200

5

1500

2

24

7

2100

2100

25

20

2400

2700

10

10

(b) target(2)

(c)

0

15

5

20

10

25

0 15

30

20

25

0

Simulation Model T wo Species : bycatch(1) and target(2)

(a) bycatch(1)

(a)

(b)

25

25

25 10

(b) target(2)

(c) 25

25

3000

3000

3000

10

30

1600

9

9

2700

2700

2700

27 1400

8

8

20

6

20

20

2400

7

20

2400

2100

20

2400

1200

6

2100

2100

24

7

21 5

15

1800

4 3

30

5

15

15

15

1800

1500

18

4 3

1500

1500

1000

15

1800

15

800

2

2 1 1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

10

25

1200

10

1200

10

10

1200

10

900

900

1

900

12

600

1 2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

90

400 600

5

Target Species 15 20

5

600

5

300

15

20

25

0

5

10

15 5

2010

2515

200

300

0

20

25

5

0

10

10

10

300

0

5

10 Bycatch Species

60

5

5

5

600

5

15

20

15

5

20

10

25

0 15

30

20

25

0

Simulation Model At each t :

max {E[y2tj ]

j2{1,...J}

⇢E[y1tj ]

rDt (j)}

Dt (j) = distance to j f rom current location

⇢ and r are institutional parameters ⇢ = shadow cost of bycatch

low ⇢ means fishermen do not internalize the external cost of bycatch.

starting location

Simulation Model At each t :

max {E[y2tj ]

j2{1,...J}

⇢E[y1tj ]

rDt (j)}

Dt (j) = distance to j f rom current location

⇢ and r are institutional parameters r = shadow cost of travel

high r means fishermen perceive an opportunity cost of not fishing.

starting location

Simulation Model At each t :

max {E[y2tj ]

j2{1,...J}

⇢E[y1tj ]

rDt (j)}

Example high ⇢ and low r represents a fishery with catch shares. low ⇢ and high r represents a fishery without catch shares.

starting location

High ρ Low

r

25

0.009 0.008

20

0.007 0.006

15

r

Low ρ Low

Revealed Production Sets

0.01

0.01

25

0.009

0.008

20

0.007

0.006

15

0.005

0.005 0.004

10

0.004

10

0.003

0.003 0.002

10

15

20

25

0.002

5

0.001

0.001 0

5

10

15

20

25

0

10

Target Species 15 20

25

5

30

5

Low ρ High r

5

High ρ High r

0.02

25

0.018 0.016

20

0

5

10 Bycatch Species

15

20

0.02

25

0.018

0.016

20

0.014

0.014 0.012

15

0.012

15

0.01

0.01 0.008

10

0.008

10

0.006

0.006 0.004

5

0.004

5

0.002

0.002

5

10

15

20

25

0

5

10

15

20

25

0

High ρ Low

r

25

0.009 0.008

20

0.007 0.006

15

r

Low ρ Low

Revealed Production Frontiers

0.01

0.01

25

0.009

0.008

20

0.007

0.006

15

0.005

0.005 0.004

10

0.004

10

0.003

0.003 0.002

10

15

20

25

0.002

5

0.001

0.001 0

5

10

15

20

25

0

10

Target Species 15 20

25

5

30

5

Low ρ High r

5

High ρ High r

0.02

25

0.018 0.016

20

0

5

10 Bycatch Species

15

20

0.02

25

0.018

0.016

20

0.014

0.014 0.012

15

0.012

15

0.01

0.01 0.008

10

0.008

10

0.006

0.006 0.004

5

0.004

5

0.002

0.002

5

10

15

20

25

0

5

10

15

20

25

0

Application: The Bering Sea Groundfish Fishery Did rights-based management induce bycatch avoidance?

brokers or wholesalers for direct sale or further processing. Since the early 2000s, twenty-

three vessels have actively participated in the fishery, ranging in size from 91 to 295 feet

Bering Sea and Aleutian Islands (median=154) with horsepower ranging from 850 to 7000 (median=2250).

²

²

ALASKA

ALASKA Red King Crab Savings Area (RKCSA) Pribilof Islands Habitat Conservation Area

Bering Sea

Aleutian Islands

Red King Crab Savings Subarea (RKCSS)

0

35 70

140

210

280

Nautical Miles 350

0 12.5 25

50

75

100

Nautical Miles 125

Figure 5.1: Map of Bering Sea and Aleutian Islands -

Generally speaking, the BSAI groundfish fishery can be divided into two fisheries: the 1

“Groundfish” refers to any fish species that live on or near the bottom of the seafloor.

The Bering Sea Groundfish Fishery • Pre-Amendment 80 (prior to 2008): - Target species TACs allocated as common property over multiple “sub-seasons” - TAC for prohibited species allocated to target species fisheries - Target fisheries typically closed due to binding bycatch TAC - particularly true for halibut - Fishermen “unable” to avoid halibut

• Post-Amendment 80 (2008 and after): - Target species and bycatch allocations vested directly into cooperatives or limited access fishery - Initially one cooperative formed: 16 vessels, 7 companies

Changes in Fishing Practices

• Large-scale shift in effort away from halibut-rich areas !

- Dark = increased effort - Light = decreased effort

January to April

-.2

Chg. in

Changes in Fishing Practices 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Year

.4 .2 0

!

-.2

Chg. in Probability (2007=0)

Halibut>10%

• Fine-scale shift in effort after hauls with a large proportion of halibut

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Year

Move if dist>=5

- Probability of moving fishing locations after a large halibut encounter (relative to 2007)

Move if dist>=7

movements of a given minimum distance relative to

effects. Z-statistics (in parentheses) are based on cluster-robust standard errors clustered on combinations

Changes in Fishing Practices of vessel, year and week (* p

Suggest Documents