Example: Calculating IEPs and Engel Curves. Demand II. Solved Example. Solved Example (II) Solved Example (III)

Professor Jay Bhattacharya Spring 2001 Example: Calculating IEPs and Engel Curves Demand II • Find the IEP and Engel Curve for a consumer with • ...
Author: Edgar Doyle
303 downloads 3 Views 57KB Size
Professor Jay Bhattacharya

Spring 2001

Example: Calculating IEPs and Engel Curves

Demand II

• Find the IEP and Engel Curve for a consumer with

• Recap: last lecture we covered: – Income Expansion Paths and Engel curves – Inferior and Normal Goods – Necessities and Luxuries – “Marshallian” Demand Curves

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

Cobb Douglass Utility Function : U ( x, y ) = xα y1−α Budget Constraint : px x + p y y = I

• To find the solution: – Solve for the Marshallian demand curves. This will automatically give you the Engel Curve – Solve each demand curve for income – Set these equations equal to each other to derive the IEP. 1

Spring 2001

Solved Example

• Find the Marshallian demand curves:

L = xα y1−α − λ ( p x x + p y y − I )

x( px , p y , I ) = α

• Calculate the first order conditions:

α

− λp x = 0

Spring 2001

éxù ∂L = α ê ú − λp y = 0 ∂y ë yû

Econ 11-Lecture 6

3

Solved Example (III) px x* α

I=

y ( p x , p y , I ) = (1 − α )

I py

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

4

What happens to demand when price changes?

• Solve each demand curve for income: I=

I px

• These demand curves are the same as the Engel curves, since they show how the optimal levels of x and y change with income. • Note that for Cobb-Douglass utility, Engel curves are linear in income.

∂L = px x + p y y − I = 0 ∂λ 1−α

2

Solved Example (II)

• Set up the Lagrangian:

∂L é yù =αê ú ∂x ëxû

Econ 11-Lecture 6

x2

p y y* 1−α

• Setting these equations equal to each other gives the income expansion path: py y* 1−α

=

(1 − α ) p x x* px x* Þ y* = α αp y

slope = −

slope = −

• For Cobb-Douglass utility, the IEP is linear.

* 1

p p2

p10 p2

x1 Spring 2001

Econ 11--Lecture 6

Econ 11-Lecture 6

5

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

6

1

Professor Jay Bhattacharya

Spring 2001

Marshallian Demand Curve

What Causes the Change in Demand?

p1

• 2 reasons why demand for x1 changes

p1*

– it is more expensive relative to x2 – consumer effectively has less income

• We label these 2 effects as:

p10

– the ‘substitution effect’ • (“Hicks” substitution effect)

– the ‘income effect’ x1 Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

7

The “Hicks” Substitution Effect

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

8

The “Hicks” Income Effect

x2

x2 The budget constraint tilts along the original utility curve until its slope reflects the new relative prices.

Then the tilted budget constraint shifts back to reflect the new budget constraint.

x1 Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

x1 9

• The substitution effect must be negative • The income effect can be positive or negative. Why?

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

10

“Hicks” vs. “Slutsky” • The “Hicks” substitution effect holds utility constant

– some goods are inferior

– rotate along the indifference curve

• The “Slutsky” substitution effect holds purchasing power constant – rotate around the original consumption bundle

• It’s easier to derive the Slutsky equation and the size of the income effect from the latter x1 inferior Spring 2001

Econ 11--Lecture 6

x1 normal Econ 11-Lecture 6

11

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

12

2

Professor Jay Bhattacharya

Spring 2001

The “Slutsky” Substitution Effect x2

The “Slutsky” Income Effect x2

x1 Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

x1 13

~

~

(+ or -) Income Effect Ι

∆Χ 1 = ∆Χ 1 + ∆Χ 1

0

– The size of the substitution effect depends upon how much of a change is needed to get to the point where the MRS is equal to the slope of the new budget constraint.

( -) Substitution Effect

• This distance depends upon the curvature of the indifference curve.

S

– If the indifference curve is flat, the substitution effect will be large. – If the indifference curve is “very convex,” the substitution effect will be small.

The “Slutsky” Equation

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

15

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

16

How large is the income effect?

How large is the substitution effect? Flatter indifference curve means larger substitution effect.

14

• The substitution effect represents a movement along an indifference curve.

= (Χ1 − Χ1 ) + (Χ1 − Χ1 ) *

Econ 11-Lecture 6

How large is the substitution effect?

Change in Total Demand ∆Χ 1 = Χ1∗ − Χ10

Spring 2001

Steeper indifference curve means smaller substitution effect.

• Intuition: The income effect will be larger, the more x1 originally purchased. • How to see this: Think about how much extra income is needed to get back the original bundle of goods when one price increases.

new price = p1* old price = p10 Spring 2001

Econ 11--Lecture 6

Econ 11-Lecture 6

17

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

18

3

Professor Jay Bhattacharya

Spring 2001

Compensated and Uncompensated Changes in Demand

How Large is the Income Effect?

p1 x10 + p20 x20 = I1 − p1* x10 + p20 x20 = − I 2 0

(

)

∆p1 x10

−∆I

Original

• “Uncompensated” Change is the total change resulting from a price change. – Marshallian Demand – What we observe • We separate the uncompensated change into 2 effects – substitution effect – income effect • “Compensated” demand is the change holding utility constant, i.e., the substitution effect.

New

Income Needed

This quantity is larger if x10 is larger. Thus:

−∆I = ∆p1 x10 Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

19

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

20

Derivation of Slutsky’s Equation

Slutsky’s Equation

∆x1 = ∆x1S + ∆x1I

• An algebraic decomposition of the total change in demand into income and substitution effects • What do the relative size and sign of the two effects imply for the change in demand?

∆x1I = =

∆x1I ∆I ∆I

∆x1 • (−∆p1 x10 ) ∆I

∆x1 = ∆x1 − S

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

21

Spring 2001

Slutsky’s Equation (in terms of rates of change) ∆x1 = ∆x1 − S

Econ 11--Lecture 6

Econ 11-Lecture 6

22

• The rate of change in demand as price changes (holding income fixed) is equal to – the rate of change in demand as prices change, adjusting income; and – the rate of change in demand as income changes holding prices fixed

∆x1 ∆x ∆x 0 = − x1 ∆p1 ∆p1 ∆I

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

Interpretation

∆x1I 0 ∆p1 x1 ∆I

S

∆x1I 0 ∆p1 x1 ∆I

I 1

23

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

24

4

Professor Jay Bhattacharya

Spring 2001

Law of Demand and Giffen Goods

Example of a Giffen Good x2

• The change in demand can be positive or negative since the income effect can be positive or negative.

• Case I: ‘Law’ of Demand – Occurs if:

p1

dx1 income effect

• Case II: ‘Giffen Good’ – Occurs if: • x1 is inferior, and • income effect > substitution effect

dx1 >0 dp x1

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

25

Spring 2001

(Own) Price Elasticity of Demand

= x1

• Fact: the price elasticity of demand tells us how the total expenditure on a good changes with price • Let T = total expenditure on x1 = x 1 p 1 • How total expenditure changes with price = dT d p1 Econ 11-Lecture 6

27

Spring 2001

If

Good is relatively inelastic

Econ 11--Lecture 6

28

T = p1x1 Good 1 is relatively elastic

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

p1

If ∞ < η1 < −1 Þ

η1 > 0 Þ

p1 dx1 + x1 x1 dp1

Total Expenditure

dT = x1 [η1 + 1] dp1

If

26

é p dx ù = x1 ê 1 1 + 1ú ë x1 dp1 û = x1 [η1 + 1]

Price Elasticity of Demand

dT 0 dp1

Econ 11-Lecture 6

dT dX = p1 1 + x1 dp1 dp1

dx p η1 = 1 1 dp1 x1

Spring 2001

x1

Good 1 is a Giffen Good x1 Econ 11-Lecture 6

29

Spring 2001

Econ 11-Lecture 6

30

5

Professor Jay Bhattacharya

Spring 2001

Relative Elasticity p1

p1

x1 Relatively Elastic Spring 2001

Econ 11--Lecture 6

Relatively Inelastic Econ 11-Lecture 6

31

6